Economic and Social Reports
Markups and inflation: Evidence from firm-level data

Release date: June 28, 2023

DOI: https://doi.org/10.25318/36280001202300600004-eng

Skip to text

Text begins

Abstract

In the past two years, Canada has experienced inflation rates that have not been seen in the past two decades. The rise of markups, i.e., price over marginal cost, can be one of the potential drivers or amplifiers of inflation. This study uses firm-level data to estimate markups in Canada before and during the COVID-19 pandemic. The results indicate that aggregate markups for non-financial businesses, excluding oil and gas industries, increased by 2.6% from the two years before the onset of COVID-19 to the second quarter of 2022. Compared with a range of inflation measures during the same period, the estimated increase in markups is relatively small. For example, during the same period, consumer price inflation, excluding energy, rose by 10.5%.

Keywords: Markups, inflation, imperfect competition, COVID-19, supply and demand shocks

Authors

Hassan Faryaar and Danny Leung are with the Economic Analysis Division, Statistics Canada. Alexandre Fortier-Labonté is with the Industrial Organization and Finance Division, Statistics Canada.

Introduction

Since the beginning of the pandemic-induced recession, the world has experienced various disruptions, including COVID-19 lockdowns, supply-chain problems and geopolitical tensions. These disruptions affected the economy in terms of both supply and demand. By consequence, prices have increased (Chart 1), and high inflation has become one of the main concerns of Canadian households (Statistics Canada, 2022, June 9; Argitis, 2022). Inflation increased from an average of 2% year over year in the pre-pandemic period to around 8% year over year in mid-2022.

Chart 1 Price indexes, 2012=100.

Data table for Chart 1 
Data table for Chart 1
Table summary
This table displays the results of Data table for Chart 1 Consumer Price Index, all items , Consumer Price Index, all items excluding energy and Gross domestic product price index, at market price, calculated using price level units of measure (appearing as column headers).
Consumer Price Index, all items Consumer Price Index, all items excluding energy Gross domestic product price index, at market price
price level
2018
Quarter 1 108.53 109.29 107.7
Quarter 2 109.40 109.77 108.4
Quarter 3 109.92 110.39 108.6
Quarter 4 109.59 110.64 107.2
2019
Quarter 1 110.28 111.62 108.6
Quarter 2 111.75 112.51 109.6
Quarter 3 112.05 113.10 109.7
Quarter 4 111.89 113.05 110.6
2020
Quarter 1 112.27 113.77 109.5
Quarter 2 111.78 114.03 108.2
Quarter 3 112.35 114.03 110.9
Quarter 4 112.76 114.42 112.5
2021
Quarter 1 113.88 115.09 116.0
Quarter 2 115.52 116.24 118.6
Quarter 3 116.92 117.41 120.1
Quarter 4 118.09 118.37 122.4
2022
Quarter 1 120.52 120.27 126.2
Quarter 2 124.24 122.90 130.0
Quarter 3 125.28 124.66 128.5
Quarter 4 125.96 125.67 127.6

Inflation can be caused by negative supply shocks, such as supply-chain disruptions, and positive demand shocks, especially during the recovery from the pandemic and post-COVID-19 period (Eickmeier and Hofmann, 2022; Shapiro, 2022).Note Assuming a perfectly competitive market, Chen and Tombe (2023) find that both positive demand and negative supply shocks had important roles in driving inflation in Canada.

Regardless of whether supply or demand shocks are dominant, researchers have argued that market power can also contribute to inflation in imperfectly competitive markets. For example, Australian researchers Quiggin and Menezes (2022) argue that when there is an increase in demand, firms with market power increase their prices for any given quantity supplied. A firm that raises prices would normally experience a decline in their quantity sold and revenue when demand is stable, but this effect is mitigated when demand is rising. They argue that while market power is not the cause of inflation, it can amplify it when demand is rising. By contrast, Stiglitz and Regmi (2022) find that the aggregate consumption in the United States during the past two years stayed mainly below its long-term trend and only moved slightly above it. The authors argue that aggregate demand is not the primary driver of inflation; instead, inflation is largely driven by supply shocks, sectoral demand shifts and exercise of market power in this context. For Canada, Tombe (2022) points out that over 70% of the increased profit levels in Canada can be traced to mining, oil and gas activities, including refining industries, where firms do not have market power because prices are set by global markets. He suggests that market power did not play a significant role in explaining the increasing profits outside these areas, but he does not examine measures of market power, per se.

This paper uses firm-level data to estimate markups, i.e., price over marginal costs (the incremental cost of producing the final unit of output), and investigates the possible rise of markups as one of the potential contributors to the recent inflation. Markups have been used to study changes in the degree of competitive pressure in the economy over time. Before the pandemic, many economies were already experiencing growing market power (De Loecker and Eeckhout, 2018; Díez and Duval, 2019). Understanding the degree of competition in an economy is important. More competitive markets are associated with higher employment, welfare and productivity, and lower prices. Moreover, rising market power in the post-COVID-19 years may threaten economic recovery because it may be an obstacle to the entry of new businesses (Georgieva et al., 2021).Note

This paper presents estimates of markups from 2018 to 2022. It focuses on the association between changes in markups and inflation, rather than on markups as a measure of the degree of competition in the economy, as short-term fluctuations in markups may not reflect a permanent structural change in the nature of competition. 

Some studies have focused on the profitability of Canadian industries during the pandemic using industry-level data. This paper focuses on estimating markups using firm-level data. While a measure of profitability such as the profit margin (revenue minus costs, divided by revenue) is driven by price relative to average costs, the markup is focused on price relative to marginal costs—the cost measure that is more relevant to a firm’s production and pricing decisions. Profit margins may increase if fixed costs (costs that do not vary with the amount of production) decline, while markups may not necessarily do so.

Demand and supply shifts and markups

In a perfectly competitive environment, prices are set by the market, and the production decisions of any single firm do not have an impact on the market price. When the economy deviates from perfect competition, an individual business has some pricing power. It can set a higher price and produce and sell less, or it can set a lower price and produce and sell more. A business may have market power because, for example, it sells a differentiated product or because there are barriers that prevent competitors from entering the market. Profit-maximizing businesses increase their production and set their price where the increase in revenue from selling the final unit of output equals the incremental cost of producing that output, where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. The price is higher than marginal revenue and marginal cost because the price applies not only to the final unit sold but to all units sold.Note Firms with more market power experience a smaller drop in quantity of output sold when they raise their prices, so the gap between their price and marginal cost will be higher. The ratio between price and marginal cost is the markup:

P t =Marku p t *M C t                                         ( 1 ) MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWGqbWdamaaBaaaleaapeGaamiDaaWdaeqaaOWdbiabg2da9iaa d2eacaWGHbGaamOCaiaadUgacaWG1bGaamiCa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbi aadshaa8aabeaak8qacaGGQaGaamytaiaadoeapaWaaSbaaSqaa8qa caWG0baapaqabaGcpeGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckaca GGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaa cckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaai iOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGG GcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacc kacaGGGcGaaiiOa8aadaqadaqaa8qacaaIXaaapaGaayjkaiaawMca aaaa@7421@

Where P t MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWGqbWdamaaBaaaleaapeGaamiDaaWdaeqaaaaa@383F@  and M C t MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWGnbGaam4qa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaadshaa8aabeaaaaa@3904@  are the price and the marginal cost of a business with market power at time t MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWG0baaaa@3710@ . From a business point of view, higher marginal costs or higher markups or both can lead to a change in prices.Note

An increase in demand may raise marginal costs because of diminishing returns (each additional amount of input generates less output). For example, Jarsulic (2022) finds that in the United States, demand shifted from the services to the commodities sector during the pandemic, and this may have raised marginal costs for commodity producers. Thus, part of the price increase is related to increased marginal costs. In some frameworks and under certain conditions, markups can also increase. Increased demand may be accompanied by less sensitivity to price increases on the part of consumers. For example, after the easing of restrictions, individuals may be so eager that they are willing to travel, despite higher prices. Profit-maximizing businesses with market power take this into account and raise their markups and prices. Different frameworks, however, predict different outcomes, so the relationship between markups and demand shocks is an empirical question.Note

Marginal costs and prices can also increase in the case of negative supply shocks. For example, rising energy prices or an increase in the price of other inputs related to supply-chain issues will increase the cost of producing and, therefore, output prices, at any given quantity (Kilian and Zhou, 2022). Also, the need to adapt production processes to post-COVID-19 realities may have led to declines in productivity and increased costs (Statistics Canada, 2023, April 18). At the same time, markups may also change in the face of supply shocks. Input shortages and rising costs may lead to the exit of less productive businesses, which would increase the market power and markups of remaining businesses. Under other conditions and frameworks, markups may also decrease with negative supply shocks,Note so empirical estimates are needed.

Methodology

To estimate markups, the paper follows De Loecker and Warzynski (2012) and De Loecker et al. (2020), which is based on the work of Hall (1988). In particular, firms minimize their costs, and from their first order conditions, the following equation can be obtained:

Marku p it = β v   Re v it Variable_Cos t it                                                    ( 2 ) MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWGnbGaamyyaiaadkhacaWGRbGaamyDaiaadchapaWaaSbaaSqa a8qacaWGPbGaamiDaaWdaeqaaOWdbiabg2da9iabek7aI9aadaWgaa WcbaWdbiaadAhaa8aabeaak8qacaGGGcWaaSaaa8aabaWdbiaadkfa caWGLbGaamODa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaadMgacaWG0baapaqabaaake aapeGaamOvaiaadggacaWGYbGaamyAaiaadggacaWGIbGaamiBaiaa dwgacaGGFbGaam4qaiaad+gacaWGZbGaamiDa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbi aadMgacaWG0baapaqabaaaaOWdbiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaaccka caGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOai aacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGa aiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckaca GGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaa cckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaai iOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGG GcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacc kacaGGGcGaaiiOa8aadaqadaqaa8qacaaIYaaapaGaayjkaiaawMca aaaa@A108@

Where Marku p it MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWGnbGaamyyaiaadkhacaWGRbGaamyDaiaadchapaWaaSbaaSqa a8qacaWGPbGaamiDaaWdaeqaaaaa@3DE6@  is the value of markups for firm i MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWGPbaaaa@3705@  at time t MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWG0baaaa@3710@ . Re v it MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWGsbGaamyzaiaadAhapaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWGPbGaamiDaaWd aeqaaaaa@3B14@  and Variable_Cos t it MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWGwbGaamyyaiaadkhacaWGPbGaamyyaiaadkgacaWGSbGaamyz aiaac+facaWGdbGaam4BaiaadohacaWG0bWdamaaBaaaleaapeGaam yAaiaadshaa8aabeaaaaa@4436@  are the revenue and the cost of variable input (i.e., operating expensesNote ) for firm i MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWGPbaaaa@3705@  at time t MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWG0baaaa@3710@ . β v MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacqaHYoGypaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWG2baapaqabaaaaa@390D@ is the output elasticity of variable input for firm i MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWGPbaaaa@3705@  determined at the industry level categorized based on the two-digit North American Industry Classification System (NAICS). The paper follows De Loecker and Warzynski (2012) and Ackerberg et al. (2015) to obtain the elasticity, β v MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacqaHYoGypaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWG2baapaqabaaaaa@390D@ . In particular, the paper estimates the following Cobb–Douglas production function:

  q it  =  β v v it  +  β k k it  +  ω it  +  it  ,                                          ( 3 ) MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaGGGcGaamyCa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaadMgacaWG0baapaqabaGc peGaaiiOaiabg2da9iaacckacqaHYoGypaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWG2b aapaqabaGcpeGaamODa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaadMgacaWG0baapaqa baGcpeGaaiiOaiabgUcaRiaacckacqaHYoGypaWaaSbaaSqaa8qaca WGRbaapaqabaGcpeGaam4Aa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaadMgacaWG0baa paqabaGcpeGaaiiOaiabgUcaRiaacckacqaHjpWDpaWaaSbaaSqaa8 qacaWGPbGaamiDaaWdaeqaaOWdbiaacckacqGHRaWkcaGGGcaccaGa e8hcI48damaaBaaaleaapeGaamyAaiaadshacaGGGcaapaqabaGcpe GaaiilaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaaccka caGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOai aacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGa aiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckaca GGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaa cckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaai iOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGG GcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacc kacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiO a8aadaqadaqaa8qacaaIZaaapaGaayjkaiaawMcaaaaa@B280@

Where q it MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWGXbWdamaaBaaaleaapeGaamyAaiaadshaa8aabeaaaaa@394E@ , v it MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWG2bWdamaaBaaaleaapeGaamyAaiaadshaa8aabeaaaaa@3953@ , k it MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWGRbWdamaaBaaaleaapeGaamyAaiaadshaa8aabeaaaaa@3948@  and ω it MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacqaHjpWDpaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWGPbGaamiDaaWdaeqaaaaa@3A25@  are the logs of deflated revenue, operating expenses, capital and productivity, respectively. β v MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacqaHYoGypaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWG2baapaqabaaaaa@390D@  and β k MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacqaHYoGypaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWGRbaapaqabaaaaa@3902@  are the elasticity of variable and capital inputs, and it  MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaccaaeaaaaaa aaa8qacqWFiiIZpaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWGPbGaamiDaiaacckaa8aa beaaaaa@3B03@  is an i.i.d. MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaWGPbGaaiOlaiaadMgacaGGUaGaamizaiaac6caaaa@3AF2@  measurement error.Note

Data

The paper uses firm-level data from the Quarterly Survey of Financial Statements (QSFS) produced by Statistics Canada. The survey collects data on financial statements of both publicly and non-publicly traded enterprises in Canada. An enterprise (hereafter, firm) can be a single corporation or a family of corporations under common ownership or control that produces consolidated financial statements.

The QSFS has three categories of firms that are classified based on their assets and revenues in each industry:

  • take-all or large firms that are always surveyed
  • medium-sized firms that are randomly surveyed
  • take-none or small firms that are below the industry threshold for assets and revenues—the small firms are not sampled; rather, they are derived by applying the quarter-to-quarter movement of sample responses to annual data compiled from administrative data.Note

The QSFS does not cover business enterprises controlled by governments or non-profit enterprises. Moreover, this paper excludes the finance and insurance (NAICS 52) and mining, quarrying, and oil and gas extraction (NAICS 21) industries because the former has different financial statements than the rest of the economy and the latter’s prices are largely driven by global markets and developments. The microdata on which the estimation is based account for around 80% of the total revenue reported in the official aggregate estimates of total revenue from the QSFS that include an imputation for the take-none portion. Therefore, the changes in the estimated markups over time using the QSFS should broadly reflect the changes in the true aggregate markup. Moreover, the exercise of market power is typically associated with larger, more dominant firms, rather than small firms.

Results

Aggregate markup

The results show that markups started rising in the third quarter of 2020, after the beginning of the pandemic. Chart 2 presents the estimated average weighted markup from the first quarter of 2018 to the second quarter of 2022. Each firm’s markup is weighted by its revenue to obtain a markup that is applicable to the aggregate output produced by all the surveyed firms. That is, the weighting takes into account that a small firm contributes less to the aggregate output in the economy than a large one.

The results show that—excluding the mining, quarrying, and oil and gas extraction sector; the finance and insurance sector; and non-profits—markups have increased by 2.6%, compared with the average markups in the two years before the pandemic. In particular, markups increased from 1.103 in 2018 and 2019 to 1.132 in the second quarter of 2022.

Chart 2 Overall weighted average markups

Data table for Chart 2 
Data table for Chart 2
Table summary
This table displays the results of Data table for Chart 2 Markup level (appearing as column headers).
Markup level
2018
Quarter 1 1.10
Quarter 2 1.10
Quarter 3 1.11
Quarter 4 1.11
2019
Quarter 1 1.10
Quarter 2 1.10
Quarter 3 1.10
Quarter 4 1.11
2020
Quarter 1 1.10
Quarter 2 1.09
Quarter 3 1.11
Quarter 4 1.11
2021
Quarter 1 1.11
Quarter 2 1.12
Quarter 3 1.12
Quarter 4 1.12
2022
Quarter 1 1.12
Quarter 2 1.13

As discussed, markups can be a potential driver of inflation. To estimate the impact of markups, the log difference of Equation (1) is taken to obtain the following relationship between the growth of prices, markups and marginal costs:

Δln P t =Δln μ t +ΔlnM C t                                                                ( 4 ) MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaqGuoGaamiBaiaad6gacaWGqbWdamaaBaaaleaapeGaamiDaaWd aeqaaOWdbiabg2da9iaabs5acaWGSbGaamOBaiabeY7aT9aadaWgaa WcbaWdbiaadshaa8aabeaak8qacqGHRaWkcaqGuoGaamiBaiaad6ga caWGnbGaam4qa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaadshaa8aabeaak8qacaGGGc GaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaaccka caGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOai aacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGa aiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckaca GGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaa cckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaai iOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGG GcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacc kacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckacaGGGcGaaiiOaiaacckapaWaaeWaaeaa peGaaGinaaWdaiaawIcacaGLPaaaaaa@9DFA@

where the left-hand side is the growth of prices, i.e., cumulative inflation, over the sample period, and the right-hand side is the growth of markups and marginal costs. The gross domestic product (GDP) price index and Consumer Price Index (CPI) excluding and including energy are used to measure the growth of prices. Table 1 compares the growth in markups with alternative price growth rates, i.e., Δln μ t Δln P t MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qadaWcaaWdaeaapeGaeuiLdqKaamiBaiaad6gacqaH8oqBpaWaaSba aSqaa8qacaWG0baapaqabaaakeaapeGaaeiLdiaadYgacaWGUbGaam iua8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaadshaa8aabeaaaaaaaa@41D9@ , for each price index. Regardless of the price measure used, the growth in markups is a relatively small fraction of the growth in prices.Note The growth in markups is 24.7%, 20.8% and 13.4% of the growth in the CPI excluding energy, CPI including energy and GDP price index, respectively. As mentioned, the weighted average markup is more applicable to aggregate output. Hence, the GDP price index can be a more appropriate price index to evaluate the relationship between inflation and markups, but the GDP price index, excluding the oil and gas sector, was not available to the authors.


Table 1
Markup versus price growth
Table summary
This table displays the results of Markup versus price growth Before the pandemic
(2018 to 2019), 2022
(second quarter), Growth and Markup growth over
price growth, i.e., Δlnμ_t/ΔlnP_t, calculated using percent units of measure (appearing as column headers).
Before the pandemic
(2018 to 2019)
2022
(second quarter)
Growth Markup growth over
price growth, i.e., Δln μ t Δln P t MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qadaWcaaWdaeaapeGaeuiLdqKaamiBaiaad6gacqaH8oqBpaWaaSba aSqaa8qacaWG0baapaqabaaakeaapeGaaeiLdiaadYgacaWGUbGaam iua8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaadshaa8aabeaaaaaaaa@41D9@
percent
Markups 1.1 1.1 2.6 Note ...: not applicable
CPI excluding energy 111.2 122.9 10.5 24.7
CPI including energy 110.4 124.2 12.5 20.8
GDP price index 108.8 130.0 19.4 13.4

The findings of this paper are consistent with studies that estimated markups using firm-level data in the United States. For example, Konczal and Lusiani (2022) find that markups after the onset of the pandemic in the United States have increased at the fastest annual pace since 1955 and reached their highest recorded level. They use the Compustat dataset, which contains financial statements of only publicly traded firms. By contrast, the QSFS dataset used in this paper covers both Canadian publicly traded firms and non-publicly traded ones. In another paper, Jarsulic (2022) uses industry-level data and shows that markups in the United States have increased during recovery periods. The author argues that the increase in markups in the 2020 recovery has been higher than that in the 2009 recovery, and in the 2020 recovery, rising markups increased prices by about 1 percentage point more than they did in the 2009 recovery. Jarsulic (2022) states that although the increased cost of production can be the main driver of inflation, it cannot be the only factor. The market power and rising markups, at least partially, can explain the surge in inflation.

Industry-level markups

Chart 3 illustrates markups at the industry level for the three sectors of manufacturing (NAICS 31, 32 and 33), wholesale trade (NAICS 41) and retail trade (NAICS 44 and 45).Note The estimated markups are weighted by the revenue of firms. The results show that markups for the manufacturing sector increased from 1.093 before the pandemic to 1.151 in the second quarter of 2022. For the wholesale trade sector, they increased from 1.066 to 1.083. Finally, for the retail trade sector, the average markups increased from 1.038 to 1.063. In contrast to the manufacturing sector, which had a sharp drop in its markups at the beginning of the pandemic, the markups in the trade sectors did not show a significant decline. This could be related to the increased demand for health-related goods and groceries at the beginning of the pandemic. Also, the retail industries were less affected by the COVID-19 lockdowns because of the essentiality of their services. For example, retail customers spent $669.6 billion in Canada in 2020, leading to a slight decline of 0.1% in operating revenue, compared with the previous year. However, retailers’ gross margins rose slightly, from 26.5% in 2019 to 26.8% in 2020. At the same time, their total operating expenses, including labour expenses, declined by 1.3% in 2020 (Statistics Canada, 2022, April 7).

Chart 3 Industry-level weighted average markups

Data table for Chart 3 
Data table for Chart 3
Table summary
This table displays the results of Data table for Chart 3 Manufacturing , Wholesale trade and Retail trade, calculated using markup level units of measure (appearing as column headers).
Manufacturing Wholesale trade Retail trade
markup level
2018
Quarter 1 1.09 1.07 1.04
Quarter 2 1.09 1.07 1.04
Quarter 3 1.09 1.07 1.04
Quarter 4 1.09 1.06 1.03
2019
Quarter 1 1.10 1.07 1.04
Quarter 2 1.09 1.06 1.04
Quarter 3 1.09 1.07 1.04
Quarter 4 1.10 1.07 1.04
2020
Quarter 1 1.05 1.05 1.03
Quarter 2 1.06 1.07 1.03
Quarter 3 1.09 1.08 1.06
Quarter 4 1.09 1.08 1.07
2021
Quarter 1 1.10 1.08 1.07
Quarter 2 1.12 1.09 1.06
Quarter 3 1.12 1.09 1.06
Quarter 4 1.14 1.09 1.06
2022
Quarter 1 1.13 1.08 1.06
Quarter 2 1.15 1.08 1.06

Conclusion

Inflation since the onset of the pandemic has become one of the main concerns of Canadian households (Statistics Canada, 2022, June 9; Argitis, 2022). Regardless of whether negative supply shocks (Stiglitz and Regmi, 2022), positive demand shocks (Tombe, 2022) or both supply and demand shocks (Chen and Tombe, 2023) are the main drivers of inflation, studies show that markups can have a potential role in amplifying inflation (Quiggin and Menezes, 2022).

This study uses firm-level data to estimate markups, a measure of market power, in Canada. The paper finds that the average markups in Canada, excluding the two sectors of finance and insurance (NAICS 52) and mining, quarrying, and oil and gas extraction (NAICS 21), increased from 1.103 in the pre-pandemic period to 1.132 in the second quarter of 2022. In other words, markups increased by 2.6% over the study period. By comparison, the CPI including energy rose 12.5%, the CPI excluding energy rose 10.5% and the GDP deflator rose 19.4%. Therefore, although the rise of markups contributed to the increase in inflation, it does not appear to be the main driver.

Economic theory does not give clear predictions of how markups respond to demand and supply shocks, so it is not possible to determine whether the observed changes in markups are in line with normal profit-maximizing behaviour of firms. Furthermore, changes in markups over the business cycle are also model dependent, so it is not clear whether the observed increase in markups will reverse itself when the impact of the recent demand and supply shocks subside. However, if high markups persist, they may be an indication of growing market power, which could hinder future economic growth and competitiveness. In addition to providing updates on the evolution of markups, future work could estimate changes in the dispersion of markups to examine whether the increase in markups applies across all firms, or whether it is concentrated among those with already high markups. Furthermore, the role of firm dynamics in accounting for changes in markups could also be explored. Aggregate markups could be driven by the exit of low-markup firms, or the reallocation of market share to firms with higher markups.

References

Ackerberg, D. A., Caves, K. and Frazer, G. (2015) Identification properties of recent production function estimators, Econometrica 83(6), 2411-2451.

Ambler, S. (2007). The costs of inflation in New Keynesian models. Bank of Canada Review2007, 7-16.

Argitis, T. (2022). Canadians have never felt worse about their finances, poll shows. Bloomberg News.

Basu, S. (2019). Are price-cost markups rising in the United States? A discussion of the evidence. Journal of Economic Perspectives33(3), 3-22.

Berman, N., Martin, P., Mayer, T. (2012). How do different exporters react to exchange rate changes? Quarterly Journal of Economics 127 (1), 437–492.

Chen, Yu, and Trevor Tombe. (2023). “The Rise (and Fall?) of Inflation in Canada: A Detailed Analysis of its Post-Pandemic Experience,” Canadian Public Policy, forthcoming.

De Loecker, J., Eeckhout, J., & Unger, G. (2020). The rise of market power and the macroeconomic implications. The Quarterly Journal of Economics135(2), 561-644.

De Loecker, J., & Eeckhout, J. (2018). Global Market Power. National Bureau of Economic Research. Working Paper Series no. 24768.

De Loecker, J., & Warzynski, F. (2012). Markups and firm-level export status. American economic review102(6), 2437-2471.

Díez, F., & Duval, R. (2019, April 3). How to Keep Corporate Power in Check. International Monetary Fund Blog.

Duval, R. A., Furceri, D., Lee, R., & Tavares, M. M. (2021). Market Power and Monetary Policy Transmission. International Monetary Fund.

Eickmeier, S., & Hofmann, B. (2022). What drives inflation? Disentangling demand and supply factors.

Ganapati, S., Shapiro, J. S., & Walker, R. (2020). Energy cost pass-through in US manufacturing: Estimates and implications for carbon taxes. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics12(2), 303-42.

Georgieva, K., Díez, F., Duval, R., & Schwarz, D. (2021, March 15). Rising Market Power—A Threat to the Recovery? Retrieved from IMF BLOG: https://www.imf.org/en/Blogs/Articles/2021/03/15/blog-rising-market-power-a-threat-to-the-recovery

Hall, R. E. (1988). The Relation between Price and Marginal Cost in U.S. Industry. Journal of Political Economy 96 (5), 921-947.

Heise, S., Karahan, F., & Şahin, A. (2022). The Missing Inflation Puzzle: The Role of the Wage‐Price Pass‐Through. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking54(S1), 7-51.

Jarsulic, M. (2022). Effective Inflation Control Requires Supply-Side Policy. Center for American Progress.

Kilian, L., and Zhou, X. (2022). The impact of rising oil prices on US inflation and inflation expectations in 2020–23. Energy Economics113, 106228.

Konczal, M., & Lusiani, N. (2022). Prices, Profits, and Power: An Analysis of 2021 Firm-Level Markups. Roosevelt Institute.

Nekarda, C. J., & Ramey, V. A. (2020). The cyclical behavior of the price‐cost markup. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking52(S2), 319-353.

Quiggin, J., & Menezes, F. (2022, July 27). Inflation is being amplified by firms with market power.

Shapiro, A. (2022). Decomposing Supply and Demand Driven Inflation. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2022-18. https://doi.org/10.24148/wp2022-18

Statistics Canada. (2022, June 9). Rising prices are affecting the ability to meet day-to-day expenses for most Canadians. The Daily.

Statistics Canada. (2022, April 7). Annual retail trade, 2020. The Daily.

Statistics Canada. (2023, April 18). Multifactor productivity growth estimates and industry productivity database, 2021. The Daily.

Stiglitz, J., & Regmi, I. (2022). The Causes of and Responses to Today’s Inflation. ROOSEVELT INSTITUTE.

Tombe, T. (2022). Are rising profits fueling inflation? The HUB.

Wang, W. (2023). Import Prices and Inflation in Canada. Economic and Social Reports. 3(5).

Weber, M., D’Acunto, F., Gorodnichenko, Y., & Coibion, O. (2022). The subjective inflation expectations of households and firms: Measurement, determinants, and implications. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 36, 157-184.

Wolman, A. L. 2001. A Primer on Optimal Monetary Policy with Staggered Price-Setting. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 87 (4): 27–52.
Date de modification :