Analytical Studies Branch Research Paper Series
The Industry Origins of Canada’s Weaker Labour Productivity Performance and the Role of Structural Adjustment in the 1990s and the 2000s

Warning View the most recent version.

Archived Content

Information identified as archived is provided for reference, research or recordkeeping purposes. It is not subject to the Government of Canada Web Standards and has not been altered or updated since it was archived. Please "contact us" to request a format other than those available.

by John R. Baldwin and Michael Willox
Economic Analysis Division
Statistics Canada

Release date: June 13, 2016 Correction date: (if required)

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Weimin Wang of Statistics Canada; Bryan Smith, Carlos Rosell and Amélie Lafrance of the Department of Finance; Pierre St-Amant of the Bank of Canada; and Larry Shute and Jianmin Tang of Industry Canada for their helpful comments. Any errors are the responsibility of the authors.

Abstract

This paper examines how much of the slowdown in productivity growth observed in Canada’s business sector between the 1990s (1990 to 1999) and the 2000s (2000 to 2014) was due to weaker productivity growth within industries and how much was due to structural adjustment. The analysis makes use of a decomposition method that differs from many of the standard labour productivity decomposition approaches commonly found in the literature and allows the contributions of changes in the importance of individual industries to be calculated. The approach developed here reveals that the inter-period slowdown was attributable almost entirely to weaker productivity growth within industries and that structural adjustment had a slight mitigating effect on the slowdown. Lower productivity growth within three industries—manufacturing; finance, insurance and real estate; and mining, oil and gas—accounted for much of the moderation in business-sector labour productivity growth in the 2000s.

Keywords: Labour productivity, structural adjustment

Executive summary

Canada’s business-sector labour productivity growth slowed by more than a quarter in the 2000s (2000 to 2014) from the pace set in the 1990s (1990 to 1999). This paper examines the extent to which this slowdown was the result of weaker productivity growth within industries (that is, whether all industries or only a relatively small number of industries experienced a slowdown) and how much of it was due to the restructuring of the economy as labour shifted between industries characterized by different productivity levels.

In this study, productivity growth for the business sector is separated into two distinct components: a direct productivity growth effectNote 1 and the effect of the changing importance of different industries—or structural adjustment. The paper estimates each of these effects for individual industries, thereby allowing inferences to be made about the extent to which the performance of individual industries was responsible for the changes in aggregate performance of the business sector as a whole.

The direct productivity growth effect captures the impact of changes in an industry’s labour productivity (measured as real value added per hour worked) while the relative importance of different industries is held constant. Structural adjustment captures the impact of the reallocation of labour across industries on aggregate productivity growth. The interdependencies of structural adjustment across industries, which other studies performing similar decompositions have overlooked, are incorporated here. These interdependencies are assessed using alternate counterfactuals with respect to the nature of the adjustment process.

The paper’s findings are as follows:

1 Introduction

During the period from 2000 to 2014 (referred to hereinafter as “the 2000s”), Canada’s business-sector labour productivity growth slowed to an average annual rate of 1.17%, from 1.61% in the 1990s (1990 to 1999). Canada’s weaker productivity performance in the 2000s contrasts with the comparatively stable performance of the U.S. business sector. Business-sector productivity growth in the United States fell slightly between the two periods, decreasing from an annual rate of 2.12% in the 1990s to 2.08% in the 2000s, a pace nearly 80% faster than that observed in Canada.

Changes in productivity have an impact on Canadians’ standard of living. Wages (after adjusting for inflation) typically grow at roughly the same pace as real labour productivity.Note 2 While other factors, such as stronger labour force participation and increasing terms of trade, also contribute to improved standards of living, productivity growth is a key driver of real gross domestic income in the long run.Note 3

To better understand the nature of Canada’s slowdown between the 1990s and the 2000s, the different ways in which industries contribute to the growth of labour productivity in Canada’s business sector will be examined here. In this study, productivity growth for the business sector is separated into two distinct components: a direct productivity growth effect and the effect of the changing relative importance of different industries—or structural adjustment.

The first component, the direct productivity growth effect (sometimes referred to as the ‘pure,’ or ‘within-industry,’ effect), captures the impact of changes in an industry’s labour productivity (measured as real value added per hour worked) while holding the relative importance of different industries constant. This component captures the effect of the change in productivity occurring within each industry.

The second component, structural adjustment, captures the impact on aggregate productivity growth of the reallocation of labour across industries. Reallocation occurs as a result of many forces. In the 2000s, Canada faced an appreciation of its currency, particularly against the U.S. dollar, increasing competition from emerging economies, rising commodity prices, and relatively weak U.S. demand for Canadian exports. These forces benefited some industries while others were adversely affected. For example, the manufacturing sector saw its average share of labour (measured as hours worked) decline from 18.8% in the 1990s to 15.0% in the 2000s; this reflects a secular decline that intensified in the 2000s. On the other hand, the share of labour in construction, which benefited from the natural-resource and housing boom as well as from low interest rates, increased 1.2 percentage points from 8.8% to 10.0%.

Separating aggregate productivity growth into these two components allows analysts to focus on each in isolation from the other. The examination of the sources of direct productivity growth—the measure of organic growth—permits an assessment of whether the productivity slowdown was widespread—and therefore perhaps endemic—or whether it came from specific sectors and therefore might be explained by specific circumstances. At the same time, the examination of the structural adjustment component allows a determination of the extent to which the overall slowdown in productivity growth came not from the performance of specific industries but from industrial restructuring.

To that end, the approach to decomposing aggregate labour productivity developed here reveals that measuring the impact of structural adjustment within one industry cannot be done without considering the effect of the structural adjustment in other industries. The interdependencies of structural adjustment across industries have typically been overlooked in studies that have attempted to assess industry contributions to aggregate labour productivity. In filling this gap, this study lays the groundwork for further debate on the nature of structural adjustment: how to better measure it and how to better understand its impact on aggregate labour productivity.

2 Analytical framework

Several studies, including those by Nordhaus (2001), Stiroh (2002), and Tang and Wang (2004), have decomposed aggregate labour productivity growth into a direct productivity growth effect and a structural adjustment effect. However, as de Avillez (2012) pointed out, the variation between methods provides complementary, rather than competing, stories as they tend to produce similar results in most cases. Stiroh’s (2002) approach, represented in Equation (1), is chosen here to begin, for two reasons: it has been widely used in the literature; and it is relatively easy to interpret since it neatly decomposes aggregate labour productivity growth by industry into the direct productivity growth effect and structural adjustment.Note 4 By comparison, the approaches followed by Nordhaus (2001), Tang and Wang (2004) and de Avillez (2012) are made more complex by the fact that they have included an interaction term, the interpretation of which is seldom agreed upon.

Δln( Y t H t )= i=1 N [ S ¯ i,t VA Δln( Y i,t H i,t )+ S ¯ i,t VA Δln( H i,t H t ) ]       ( 1 ) MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aaatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaGaeuiLdqKaci iBaiaac6gadaqadaqaamaaliaabaGaamywamaaBaaaleaacaWG0baa beaaaOqaaiaadIeadaWgaaWcbaGaamiDaaqabaaaaaGccaGLOaGaay zkaaGaeyypa0ZaaabCaeaadaWadaqaaiqadofagaqeamaaDaaaleaa ieGaqaaaaaaaaaWdbiaa=LgacaWFSaGaa8hDaaWdaeaacaWGwbGaam yqaaaak8qacaqGuoGaaeiBaiaab6gadaqadaWdaeaapeWaaSGaa8aa baWdbiaa=LfapaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWFPbGaa8hlaiaa=rhaa8aabe aaaOqaa8qacaWFibWdamaaBaaaleaapeGaa8xAaiaa=XcacaWF0baa paqabaaaaaGcpeGaayjkaiaawMcaaiabgUcaR8aaceWGtbGbaebada qhaaWcbaWdbiaa=LgacaWFSaGaa8hDaaWdaeaacaWGwbGaamyqaaaa k8qacaqGuoGaaeiBaiaab6gadaqadaWdaeaapeWaaSGaa8aabaWdbi aa=HeapaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWFPbGaa8hlaiaa=rhaa8aabeaaaOqa a8qacaWFibWdamaaBaaaleaapeGaa8hDaaWdaeqaaaaaaOWdbiaawI cacaGLPaaaa8aacaGLBbGaayzxaaaaleaacaWGPbGaeyypa0JaaGym aaqaaiaad6eaa0GaeyyeIuoakmaabmaabaWdbiaaigdaa8aacaGLOa Gaayzkaaaaaa@6D72@

The left-hand side of Equation (1) is the percentage change in aggregate labour productivity growth expressed as the change in the logarithmic value ( Δln MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacqqHuoarieaacaWFSbGaa8NBaaaa@39CB@ ) of real value added ( Y MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWGzbaaaa@375E@ ) per hour worked H MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWGibaaaa@374D@ ) for a given period of time ( t MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWG0baaaa@3779@ ). On the right-hand side, the first term in square brackets represents industry i MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWGPbaaaa@376E@ ’s contribution to aggregate productivity from the direct productivity growth effect, and the second term is a measure of industry i MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWGPbaaaa@376E@ ’s contribution that comes from structural adjustment. By construction, these two terms equal aggregate productivity growth when summed across all industries. The direct productivity growth effect for industry i MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWGPbaaaa@376E@ is calculated by multiplying the industry’s weight ( S ¯ i,t VA MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaGabm4uayaara Waa0baaSqaaiaadMgacaGGSaGaamiDaaqaaiaadAfacaWGbbaaaaaa @3B4C@ ) by the percentage change in its labour productivity ( Δln( Y i,t / H i,t ) MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaaMaeuiLdq KaciiBaiaac6gakmaabmaajaaybaGcdaWcgaqaaiaadMfadaWgaaWc baGaamyAaiaacYcacaWG0baabeaaaOqaaiaadIeadaWgaaWcbaGaam yAaiaacYcacaWG0baabeaaaaaajaaycaGLOaGaayzkaaaaaa@436A@ ). The contribution from structural adjustment for industry i MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWGPbaaaa@376E@ is calculated as the industry’s weight multiplied by the percentage change in its labour share ( Δln( H i,t / H t ) MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaqGuoGaaeiBaiaab6gakmaabmaajaaypaqaaOWaaSGbaeaa ieGapeGaa8hsa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaa=LgacaWFSaGaa8hDaaWdae qaaaGcbaWdbiaa=HeapaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWF0baapaqabaaaaaqc aa2dbiaawIcacaGLPaaaaaa@421A@ ), which is expressed as the growth in the ratio of industry i MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWGPbaaaa@376E@ ’s hours worked to the hours worked in the aggregate sector. Stiroh (2002) calculated industry weights as the share of industry i MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWGPbaaaa@376E@ ’s nominal value added ( VA MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWGwbGaamyqaaaa@3821@ ) in the aggregate sector averaged over the current and previous periods, t MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWG0baaaa@3779@ and t1 MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWG0bGaeyOeI0IaaGymaaaa@3921@ , respectively, as represented in Equation (2).

S ¯ i,t VA = ( V A i,t-1 V A t-1  +  V A i,t V A t )/2      ( 2 ) MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aaatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaGabm4uayaara Waa0baaSqaaGqacabaaaaaaaaapeGaa8xAaiaa=XcacaWF0baapaqa aiaadAfacaWGbbaaaOWdbiabg2da9maalyaabaWaaeWaa8aabaWdbm aaliaapaqaa8qacaWFwbGaa8xqa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaa=LgacaWF SaGaa8hDaGqaaiaa+1cacaGFXaaapaqabaaakeaapeGaa8Nvaiaa=f eapaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWF0bGaa4xlaiaa+fdaa8aabeaaaaGcpeGa aiiOaiabgUcaRiaacckadaWccaWdaeaapeGaa8Nvaiaa=feapaWaaS baaSqaa8qacaWFPbGaa8hlaiaa=rhaa8aabeaaaOqaa8qacaWFwbGa a8xqa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaa=rhaa8aabeaaaaaak8qacaGLOaGaay zkaaaabaGaaGOmaaaapaWaaeWaaeaapeGaaGOmaaWdaiaawIcacaGL Paaaaaa@570E@

An increase (decrease) in productivity of an industry leads directly to a larger (smaller) direct productivity growth effect in absolute ters. This effect will be absolutely larger (smaller) if the industry has a relatively larger (smaller) share of nominal value-added output. This occurs when the industry has a larger (smaller) share of labour and a relatively high nominal output per worker.

The calculation of the impact of a change in the importance of an industry is more complex. If an industry’s labour share increases (decreases), its contribution to aggregate productivity will also increase (decrease)—as shown in the second term in square brackets in Equation (1). As with the direct productivity growth component, an industry’s contribution from structural adjustment will be larger when the industry has a relatively larger share of nominal value-added output.

There is, however, an important difference in how the impact of a change in a particular industry’s importance needs to be assessed. For the direct productivity growth effect, a change in one industry’s labour productivity does not necessarily change the productivity of any other industry. Thus, the impact of one industry can be estimated independently of the effect of another industry. In this case, productivity growth among industries generally is not a zero-sum game, in which one industry’s gain is another’s loss.

In contrast, measuring structural adjustment requires that the labour shares for all industries sum to one (or 100%); therefore, an increase in the labour share of one industry must be offset by a decrease of the exact same magnitude in one or more other industries. Note that the second term in square brackets of Equation (1) accounts only for the structural adjustment that occurs in a single industry (industry i MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWGPbaaaa@376E@ ) when, for instance, its labour share increases. This term does not capture the decline in the labour shares of the other industries that must accompany this increase. The effect on all other industries of one industry growing in relative terms is effectively treated as zero; this causes the individual industry structural adjustment effect, when measured independently, to be incorrectly estimated. For this reason, many studies that use this decomposition refer only to the aggregate structural effect derived as the sum of all industry effects; they do not refer to individual industry structural effects.

The production of accurate single industry estimates that take into account interdependencies across industries requires the stipulation of where the labour share gains (losses) come from—a counterfactual.Note 5Note 6The counterfactual developed here assumes that the labour share gain (loss) for an industry comes from (is distributed to) all other industries in proportion to their hours worked at the beginning of the period—a result that would be generated by a stochastic process that presumes the labour share of all other industries has the same probability of being shifted to the industry in question, which may be referred to as a “stochastic” counterfactual.Note 7 This is equivalent to assuming that, without the share change in industry i MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWGPbaaaa@376E@ , there would have been no change in the relative share of any industry. For illustration, an alternative “gainers-versus-losers” counterfactual, in which industries that gain labour share do so directly from those that lose labour share, is described in the Appendix.

The effect of inter-industry structural adjustment using the above assumptions is measured by means of a modified version of the Stiroh formula, that is:

Δln( Y t H t )= i=1 N [ S ¯ i,t VA Δln( Y i,t H i,t )+ S ¯ i,t VA Δln( H i,t H t )+ j=1,ji N S ¯ j,t VA Δln( H j,t i H t ) ] ,     ( 3 ) MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aaatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qacaqGuoGaaeiBaiaab6gadaqadaWdaeaapeWaaSaaa8aabaacbiWd biaa=LfapaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWF0baapaqabaaakeaapeGaa8hsa8 aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaa=rhaa8aabeaaaaaak8qacaGLOaGaayzkaaGa eyypa0ZaaybCaeqal8aabaWdbiaadMgacqGH9aqpcaaIXaaapaqaa8 qacaWGobaan8aabaWdbiabggHiLdaakmaadmaapaqaaiqadofagaqe amaaDaaaleaapeGaa8xAaiaa=XcacaWF0baapaqaaiaadAfacaWGbb aaaOWdbiaabs5acaqGSbGaaeOBamaabmaapaqaa8qadaWcaaWdaeaa peGaa8xwa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaa=LgacaWFSaGaa8hDaaWdaeqaaa GcbaWdbiaa=HeapaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWFPbGaa8hlaiaa=rhaa8aa beaaaaaak8qacaGLOaGaayzkaaGaey4kaSYdaiqadofagaqeamaaDa aaleaapeGaa8xAaiaa=XcacaWF0baapaqaaiaadAfacaWGbbaaaOWd biaabs5acaqGSbGaaeOBamaabmaapaqaa8qadaWcaaWdaeaapeGaa8 hsa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaa=LgacaWFSaGaa8hDaaWdaeqaaaGcbaWd biaa=HeapaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWF0baapaqabaaaaaGcpeGaayjkai aawMcaaiabgkHiTmaawahabeWcpaqaa8qacaWGQbGaeyypa0JaaGym aiaacYcacaWGQbGaeyiyIKRaamyAaaWdaeaapeGaamOtaaqdpaqaa8 qacqGHris5aaGcpaGabm4uayaaraWaa0baaSqaa8qacaWGQbGaaiil aiaadshaa8aabaGaamOvaiaadgeaaaGcpeGaaeiLdiaabYgacaqGUb WaaeWaa8aabaWdbmaalaaapaqaa8qacaWFibWdamaaDaaaleaapeGa a8NAaiaa=XcacaWF0baapaqaa8qacaWFPbaaaaGcpaqaa8qacaWFib WdamaaBaaaleaapeGaa8hDaaWdaeqaaaaaaOWdbiaawIcacaGLPaaa aiaawUfacaGLDbaacaGGGcGaaiila8aadaqadaqaa8qacaaIZaaapa GaayjkaiaawMcaaaaa@8D0A@

where the first term on the right-hand side in square brackets is the direct productivity growth effect, as in Equation (1). The second term in square brackets is the own-industry structural adjustment term, which is also unchanged from Equation (1). This term does not in any way capture how other industries’ labour shares change in response to the change in industry i MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWGPbaaaa@376E@ ’s labour share. The third term on the right-hand side in square brackets measures the inter-industry structural adjustment and is the additional term—it accounts for the corresponding change in all other industries’ labour shares. The inter-industry structural adjustment term for each of the other j MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWGQbaaaa@376F@ industries is defined as

H j,t i H t = H j,t1 H t1 ( H i,t H t H i,t1 H t1 ) H j,t1 ( H t1 H i,t1 ) .     (4) MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aaatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaaeaaaaaaaaa8 qadaWcaaWdaeaaieGapeGaa8hsa8aadaqhaaWcbaWdbiaa=Pgaieaa caGFSaGaa8hDaaWdaeaapeGaa8xAaaaaaOWdaeaapeGaa8hsa8aada WgaaWcbaWdbiaa=rhaa8aabeaaaaGcpeGaeyypa0ZaaSaaa8aabaWd biaa=HeapaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWFQbGaa4hlaiaa=rhacqGHsislca aIXaaapaqabaaakeaapeGaa8hsa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaa=rhacqGH sislcaaIXaaapaqabaaaaOWdbiabgkHiTmaabmaapaqaa8qadaWcaa WdaeaapeGaa8hsa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaa=LgacaGFSaGaa8hDaaWd aeqaaaGcbaWdbiaa=HeapaWaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWF0baapaqabaaaaO WdbiabgkHiTmaalaaapaqaa8qacaWFibWdamaaBaaaleaapeGaa8xA aiaacYcacaWF0bGaeyOeI0IaaGymaaWdaeqaaaGcbaWdbiaabIeapa WaaSbaaSqaa8qacaWF0bGaeyOeI0IaaGymaaWdaeqaaaaaaOWdbiaa wIcacaGLPaaadaWcaaWdaeaapeGaa8hsa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaa=P gacaGGSaGaa8hDaiabgkHiTiaaigdaa8aabeaaaOqaa8qadaqadaWd aeaapeGaa8hsa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaa=rhacqGHsislcaaIXaaapa qabaGcpeGaeyOeI0Iaa8hsa8aadaWgaaWcbaWdbiaa=LgacaGGSaGa a8hDaiabgkHiTiaaigdaa8aabeaaaOWdbiaawIcacaGLPaaaaaGaaG jcVlaayIW7caaMi8UaaGjcVlaac6cacaGGOaGaaGinaiaacMcaaaa@759C@

The sum of the inter-industry structural adjustment terms in the other j MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWGQbaaaa@376F@ industries measures the impact of the offsetting labour share decline (increase) when the labour share of industry i MathType@MTEF@5@5@+= feaagKart1ev2aqatCvAUfeBSjuyZL2yd9gzLbvyNv2CaerbuLwBLn hiov2DGi1BTfMBaeXatLxBI9gBaerbd9wDYLwzYbItLDharqqtubsr 4rNCHbGeaGqiVu0Je9sqqrpepC0xbbL8F4rqqrFfpeea0xe9Lq=Jc9 vqaqpepm0xbba9pwe9Q8fs0=yqaqpepae9pg0FirpepeKkFr0xfr=x fr=xb9adbaqaaeGaciGaaiaabeqaamaabaabaaGcbaqcaageaaaaaa aaa8qacaWGPbaaaa@376E@ increases (decreases). This sum constitutes the required changes in the labour shares of other industries that occur in response to a change in any particular industry’s labour share. Inclusion of this term is required to measure the full impact of a change in the relative importance of a particular industry. Simultaneous consideration of the own-industry and inter-industry structural terms has the effect of producing a more complete measure of the total structural adjustment that should be attributed to any one industry.Note 8 However, it does not change the estimate of the overall impact of structural adjustment across all industries because the individual inter-industry terms of all industries sum approximately to zero.Note 9

3 The aggregate impacts of the direct labour productivity growth and structural adjustment effects in the 1990s and the 2000s

Estimates of differences in both the aggregate direct productivity growth component and the aggregate structural adjustment component between the 1990s and the 2000s reveal that the origins of the slowdown in Canada’s aggregate business-sector productivity growth are associated mostly with overall direct productivity growth effects rather than with the overall impact of structural adjustment.Note 10

In the 1990s, the changes in business-sector labour productivity came largely from the positive impact of the aggregate annual direct productivity growth component (+1.80%), which was slightly offset by the aggregate structural adjustment component (-0.18%) (Chart 1). By comparison, the average aggregate annual direct productivity growth component (+0.94%) and the aggregate structural adjustment component (+0.23%) in the 2000s were both positive. In the 1990s, the direct effect contributed all of the growth in productivity. In the 2000s, the direct term contributed just over three-quarters of the growth in productivity.

The aggregate direct productivity growth component was reduced by half between the 1990s to the 2000s. In contrast, the impact of the aggregate structural adjustment contribution increased 0.41 percentage points. This change in the contribution of structural adjustment, turning from negative in the 1990s to positive in the 2000s, helped mitigate the overall slowdown resulting from weaker direct productivity growth in some industries.

Description for Chart 1
Data table for Chart 1
Table summary
This table displays the results of Data table for Chart 1. The information is grouped by Growth components (appearing as row headers), 1990s and 2000s, calculated using percent units of measure (appearing as column headers).
Growth components 1990s 2000s
percent
Business-sector productivity 1.61 1.17
Direct productivity 1.80 0.94
Structural adjustment -0.18 0.23

Taking note of the individual industry productivity growth rates and changes in labour shares provides important context for estimating the impact of individual industries on the aggregate direct effect term. Table 1 contains the changes in productivity growth at the industry level over the two periods. The largest declines between the two periods (in decreasing order) occurred in mining, oil and gas; manufacturing; and finance, insurance and real estate. Excluding smaller declines in utilities and transportation and warehousing, all other industries experienced improved productivity growth in the 2000s compared with the 1990s. The largest improvements between the two periods occurred in the industries that had the poorest performance in the 1990s (arts and entertainment, other private services and accommodation and food), which continued to perform poorly in the 2000s compared with the business sector as a whole.

The mining, oil and gas sector, which recorded an annualized 2.92% decline in labour productivity in the 2000s, contrasts with every other industry in this regard: labour productivity in the other industries examined grew at a simple average rate of 1.36% per year during this period.Note 11 As well, the mining, oil and gas sector had the largest deceleration in labour productivity (+6.08 percentage points) from the average annual growth rate recorded in the 1990s. Labour productivity growth in mining, oil and gas was among the fastest of all industries in the 1990s, expanding at an annual pace of 3.16%; by contrast, labour productivity growth was 1.61% in the business sector during the same period. The strong productivity performance in mining, oil and gas relative to that in most other industries during the 1990s was mostly due to the decline in hours worked. Hours worked in mining, oil and gas fell 0.61% annually, while hours worked in the business sector expanded at an annual pace of 1.13%. Despite the contraction in labour, real value added in the mining, oil and gas sector grew at a rate of 2.53% per year in the 1990s, a rate moderately slower than that recorded for the business sector (+2.74%).

After the mining, oil and gas sector, the next-largest productivity slowdown was observed in manufacturing, where productivity growth decreased 1.83 percentage points, falling from 3.42% annual growth to 1.59% between the two time periods, while the finance, insurance and real estate sector recorded a decline of 1.46 percentage points.

An examination of the productivity growth rates by industry alone suggests that the mining, oil and gas sector was the key source of Canada’s productivity slowdown. However, when relative size of industries is taken into account, the industry origins of the slowdown across mining, oil and gas; manufacturing; and finance, insurance and real estate converge, while the slowdown for utilities and transportation and warehousing become comparatively minor (Table 2). The increased similarity, especially between mining, oil and gas and manufacturing, reflects the fact that nominal value added (which serves as weights) in the mining, oil and gas sector is just over half the size of that in manufacturing and roughly two-thirds as large as that in finance, insurance and real estate on average over the period from 2000 to 2014. When industry weights are taken into account, the contribution from direct productivity growth in these three industries accounted for 0.46, 0.47 and 0.23 percentage points, respectively, of the decline in business-sector productivity growth between the two periods.

4 Changes in industry labour shares in the 1990s and the 2000s

Restructuring that affected the relative importance of industries took place between the 1990s and the 2000s (Table 3). The manufacturing sector experienced the largest absolute change in labour share, falling from 18.76% to 14.99% (a 20% decline). Some of the largest proportionate changes occurred in administration and waste management (+44%) and agriculture, forestry and fishing (-39%). Other industries that experienced large absolute changes in labour shares include professional, scientific and technical services and construction. Even though the mining, oil and gas sector had a 24% gain in its labour share, increasing in absolute terms from 1.47% to 1.82%, the gain was small in relative terms.Note 12

5 The importance of total structural adjustment by industry in the 1990s and the 2000s

In this section, total structural adjustment is estimated as the sum of two terms. The first term is own-industry structural adjustment as measured by the second term on the right-hand sides of both Equation (1) and Equation (3). However, as noted in Section 2, the own-industry term for an individual industry is only a partial measure of the impact of a change in labour share of that industry on structural adjustment. Interpreting the own-industry term as an industry’s impact on total structural adjustment is misleading since it is a partial derivative. What is required is the equivalent of a total derivative.Note 13 It is only once the impact of interdependencies associated with labour reallocation across industries—what is referred to here as the inter-industry structural adjustment term—is subtracted from the own-industryterm that the total impact of an industry-level structural adjustment can be estimated.Note 14 A comparison of the two for select industries reveals the size of the potential error from not taking into account the interdependencies (Table 4).Note 15

A large adjustment is required for the manufacturing sector. The own-industry component suggests that, in the 2000s, manufacturing’s structural adjustment effect subtracted almost half a percentage point from business-sector productivity growth. However, using only this component to measure the total impact of increasing manufacturing’s share is misleading since the manufacturing sector’s inter-industry component has the opposite sign, and at -0.41 percentage points is nearly as large. The total structural adjustment is the sum of these two terms (own-industry and inter-industry), which is close to zero (-0.01 percentage points). This suggests that total structural adjustment for the manufacturing sector subtracted almost nothing from productivity growth in the business sector and reflects the fact that the manufacturing sector’s level of labour productivity in the 2000s was only moderately higher than the average for the business sector. Therefore, a large amount of structural adjustment, as occurred in manufacturing, does not necessarily translate into a large change in aggregate labour productivity.

Like the manufacturing sector, agriculture, forestry and fishing—a low-productivity industry—lost labour share in the 2000s. The large inter-industry component (+0.13 percentage points) more than offset the own-industry component (-0.08 percentage points) for this sector. The relative reallocation of labour resources away from this low-productivity industry to other industries that, on average, had higher productivity produced an overall positive contribution from total structural adjustment of 0.05 percentage points to business-sector productivity growth.

The industries that gained labour share also had offsetting own-industry and inter-industry terms. For example, mining, oil and gas gained labour share and had a large positive own-industry structural term (+0.38 percentage points) in the 2000s. This gain came from comparatively lower-productivity industries, resulting in a much smaller inter-industry effect of -0.06 percentage points. The two terms summed to a positive total structural effect of 0.31 percentage points.

Finance, insurance and real estate also gained labour share over this period and had a positive own-industry structural impact (+0.10 percentage points). As was the case with mining, oil and gas, the productivity level for finance, insurance and real estate was above the average for the business sector. By assumption of stochastic shifts in labour share, one concludes that gains in this sector came largely from industries with relatively lower productivity levels. Thus, the offsetting impact of the inter-industry adjustment was comparatively small (-0.06 percentage points), and resulted in a positive total structural effect of 0.04 percentage points.

Construction, a low-productivity industry, also had gains in labour share in the 2000s. Its own-industry term was 0.25 percentage points, but its inter-industry term was -0.30 percentage points. Construction’s labour-share gain came from industries that on average had higher productivity than it did. This resulted in a negative contribution from total structural adjustment of -0.06 percentage points.

These results reveal that the changes due to structural adjustment attributed to individual industries are smaller in absolute terms than those that would be obtained if only the own-industry term were calculated, though there still were positive structural effects in a small number of industries.

6 The combined impact of direct labour productivity growth and total structural adjustment from the 1990s to the 2000s

A comparison of direct productivity growth and structural adjustment effects allows an evaluation of the sources of overall productivity growth between the 1990s and the 2000s (Tables 5 and 6). Several conclusions emerge.

First, the mining, oil and gas sector’s negative contribution from its direct productivity growth effect between the two periods (-0.46 percentage points) was largely offset by the positive impact on total structural adjustment (+0.37 percentage points) from the growth in the relative importance of this sector. The overall contribution of mining, oil and gas added 0.10 percentage points and 0.01 percentage points to business-sector productivity growth in the 1990s and the 2000s, respectively. The mining, oil and gas sector contributed to the productivity slowdown, but did so to a lesser extent than its direct productivity growth alone might suggest. This sector’s contribution from both total structural adjustment and the direct productivity growth effect between the two periods declined 0.09 percentage points, which accounts for 20.2% of the overall inter-period decline in business-sector labour productivity growth.

Second, total structural adjustment associated with the manufacturing sector’s decline had only a marginal impact, subtracting 0.01 percentage points from business-sector productivity growth. The direct productivity growth effect, however, had a substantial impact, falling from 0.76 percentage points in the 1990s to 0.29 percentage points in the 2000s. The direct productivity growth effect thus subtracted an additional 0.47 percentage points from business-sector productivity growth. The manufacturing sector’s contribution from both total structural adjustment and the direct productivity growth effect between the two periods declined 0.48 percentage points, which accounts for 107.2% of the overall inter-period decline in business-sector labour productivity growth. The manufacturing sector’s contribution from the direct productivity growth effect alone was 104.6%. The fact that the manufacturing sector’s contribution was larger than 100% indicates that the sum of the changes in contributions between the two periods from the remaining industries was positive.

Third, another industry that contributed substantially to the productivity slowdown was the finance, insurance and real estate sector. As was the case with manufacturing, this sector’s contribution to direct productivity growth slowed sharply between the two periods, falling from 0.41 percentage points in the 1990s to 0.18 percentage points in the 2000s. It differed from manufacturing, however, in that its increasing labour share made a modest positive contribution from total structural adjustment, rising from -0.01 percentage points in the 1990s to 0.04 percentage points in the 2000s. This sector’s contribution from both total structural adjustment and the direct productivity growth effect between the two periods declined 0.17 percentage points, which accounts for 38.8% of the overall inter-period decline in business-sector labour productivity growth.

The overall declines in these three industries were partially offset by stronger contributions from four service-sector industries: other private services; accommodation and food services; professional, science and technical services; and wholesale trade. The increases in these sectors’ contributions were mostly attributable to stronger direct productivity growth, which raised aggregate labour productivity 0.28 percentage points more than if those industries’ contributions had been unchanged.

7 Conclusion

Canada’s productivity performance deteriorated from 1.61% annually in the 1990s to just 1.17% between the 1990s and the 2000s. This paper examined the extent to which this slowdown was the result of weaker productivity growth within industries and how much of it was due to the restructuring of the economy as labour shifted between industries characterized by different productivity levels. This analysis reveals the degree to which the slowdown was broadly based across several industries or was more narrowly focused on a select few.

The decline in productivity growth between the 1990s and the 2000s was not widespread. Three industries—manufacturing; mining, oil and gas; and finance, insurance and real estate—accounted for much of the decline. The contribution from direct productivity growth in these three industries subtracted 0.47, 0.46 and 0.23 percentage points, respectively, from annual business-sector productivity growth between the two periods. The overall decline, therefore, was industry-specific, and explanations for the productivity slowdown need to be sought in the events affecting these sectors.

While changes in industry structure occurred over both decades, restructuring did not contribute materially to lower aggregate productivity growth rates in either period. In the 1990s, all of the gains in business-sector labour productivity came from the aggregate annual direct productivity growth component (+1.80%), while the aggregate structural adjustment component (‐0.18%) detracted slightly from growth. By comparison, annual direct productivity growth was lower (+0.94%) in the 2000s, but structural adjustment was higher and positive (+0.23%) during this period and thus attenuated the decline in overall productivity growth.

The 2000s were the period when manufacturing lost a substantial amount of labour share and when mining, oil and gas as well as construction experienced increases in their labour shares. During this time, the resource boom favoured the latter two industries, and the concomitant appreciation of the Canadian dollar, weaker U.S. demand, and increased competition from emerging economies reduced the manufacturing sector’s relative performance in export markets and led to excess capacity and a decline in productivity growth in this sector.Note 16 Changes in the importance of one industry—mining, oil and gas—accounted for most of the increase in the business sector’s total structural adjustment. Declines in the importance of the manufacturing sector had virtually no impact on this component due to the fact that its average level of labour productivity in the 2000s was only moderately higher than that of the business sector. Consideration of the effect of declines in productivity growth within individual industries and the effect of changes in their relative importance reveals that manufacturing contributed significantly to the overall decline in productivity growth as a result of its internal slowdown, not on account of its decline in relative importance. The analysis also reveals that the slowdown in productivity growth experienced by mining, oil and gas was largely offset by the increase in the labour share of this sector. The productivity level of this sector—though not its growth—was well above the average. The productivity slowdown in finance, insurance and real estate can be similarly explained—although the offsetting impact of structural adjustment here was small by comparison. In this limited sense, industry restructuring matters for productivity performance; however, in the case of these two sectors, the direct effect of the slowdown in productivity growth within each mattered just as much or more.

8 Appendix

The counterfactual used in this study—the “stochastic” counterfactual—distributes labour shares in proportion to the original importance of all industries. An alternative counterfactual—the “gainers-versus-losers” counterfactual—postulates that industries gain labour share at the expense of those that lose labour share. Consideration of the gainers-versus-losers counterfactual, however, does not change the fundamental conclusions based on the stochastic counterfactual.

A comparison of the results from the two counterfactuals is presented in Appendix Table 1. Two noteworthy differences between the results are observed: (1) the choice of counterfactual had almost no impact on inter-industry estimates for the 1990s; and (2) the estimates for the gainers-versus-losers counterfactual were modestly higher in the 2000s than in the 1990s. Despite the modestly different estimates for inter-industry structural adjustment terms, the gainers-versus-losers counterfactual indicates that manufacturing followed by the mining, oil and gas and the finance, insurance and real estate sectors were the three largest contributors to the business-sector labour productivity slowdown in the period from 2000 to 2014.

References

Baldwin, John R., and Wulong Gu. 2006. “Plant Turnover and Productivity Growth in Canadian Manufacturing.” Industrial and Corporate Change 15 (3): 417–465.

Baldwin, John R., Wulong Gu, Ryan Macdonald, and Beiling Yan. 2014. Productivity: What Is It? How Is It Measured? What Has Canada’s Performance Been Over the Period 1961 to 2012? The Canadian Productivity Review, no. 38. Statistics Canada Catalogue 15-206-X. Ottawa: Statistics Canada.

Baldwin, John R., Wulong Gu and Beiling Yan. 2013. “Export Growth, Capacity Utilization, and Productivity Growth: Evidence from Canadian Manufacturing Plants.” Review of Income and Wealth 59 (4): 665–688.

Baldwin, John R., and Mohammed Rafiquzzaman. 1995. Restructuring in the Canadian Manufacturing Sector from 1970 to 1990: Industry and Regional Dimensions of Job Turnover. Analytical Studies Branch Research Paper Series, no. 78. Statistics Canada Catalogue no. 11F0019M. Ottawa: Statistics Canada.

Bradley, Celeste, and Andrew Sharpe. 2009. “A Detailed Analysis of the Productivity Performance of Oil and Gas Extraction in Canada” Research Report no. 2009-08.

de Avillez, Ricardo. 2012. “Sectoral contributions to labour productivity growth in Canada: Does the choice of decomposition formula matter?” International Productivity Monitor, Centre for the Study of Living Standards no. 24 (fall): 97–117.

Denison, Edward F. 1979. Accounting for Slower Economic Growth. The United States in the 1970s. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution.

Nordhaus, William D. 2001. Alternative Methods for Measuring Productivity Growth. NBER Working Paper Series, no. 8095. Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Sharpe, Andrew and Bert Waslander. 2014. “The Impact of the Oil Boom on Canada’s Labour Productivity Performance, 2000-2012” Research Report no. 2014-05.

Stiroh, Kevin J. 2002. “Information technology and the U.S. productivity revival: What do the industry data say?” The American Economic Review 92 (5): 1559–1576.

Tang, Jianmin, and Weimin Wang. 2004. “Sources of aggregate labour productivity growth in Canada and the United States.” Canadian Journal of Economics 37 (2): 421–444.

Date modified: