Main article
Archived Content
Information identified as archived is provided for reference, research or recordkeeping purposes. It is not subject to the Government of Canada Web Standards and has not been altered or updated since it was archived. Please "contact us" to request a format other than those available.
- Analytical Framework
- Data source and summary statistics
- Empirical specification and results
- Conclusion
1 Analytical Framework
This section draws upon theoretical and empirical work on plant exit from both the industrial-organization and international-trade literature, and outlines a set of testable hypotheses that we will examine in the following sections.
1.1 Plant death and exchange rate
Very little work has been done on the relationship between plant exit and changes in exchange rates, either theoretically or empirically. Here we make use of the recent heterogeneous-firm model of trade developed by Bernard et al. (2003) and Melitz and Ottaviano (2008).
Bernard et al. (2003) adapt the Ricardian model to firm-specific comparative advantage. The authors calibrate their model to U.S. plant-level statistics and U.S trade data. Using this model, they simulate and obtain comparative statistics on the impacts of globalization and dollar appreciation on productivity and plant entry and exit in the U.S. manufacturing sector. They found that U.S-dollar appreciation raises U.S manufacturing productivity. Part of the gain in aggregate productivity is due to the exiting of less productive domestic producers. 1
Melitz and Ottaviano (2008) develop a monopolistically competitive model of trade with heterogeneous firms producing a horizontally differentiated good with a single production factor of labour in a general equilibrium setting. Firms are heterogeneous in terms of efficiency, and markets differ with respect to the "toughness" of competition in terms of the number and average efficiency level of competing firms. Higher efficiency is modeled as producing a greater variety at lower marginal cost. A critical cut-off cost threshold is determined when firms earn zero profit. An entering firm would immediately exit if its profit level were negative (with above-cut-off cost).
Trade is related to the toughness of competition in a product market, which then feeds back into the selection and reallocation of heterogeneous domestic producers and exporters in that market. A unilateral liberalization by the home country (a tariff cut at home, holding tariffs at foreign-country constant) increases import competition at home and generates a decrease in its threshold cost cut-off, forcing some of the less efficient plants at home to shut down.
The Melitz and Ottaviano (2008) model with asymmetric trade costs can be used to predict the effects of exchange-rate fluctuations on plant dynamics. An appreciation of a home currency is equivalent to lowering home tariffs and raising foreign tariffs. An appreciation represents decreased export-market opportunities on the export side and an increased level of import competition on the import side. It induces the least efficient plants to shut down operations. The opposite occurs when a currency depreciates.
Both the Bernard et al. (2003) and Melitz and Ottaviano (2008) models lead to:
- Hypothesis 1: An appreciating currency increases the exit rate of less productive plants. In other words, the effect in terms of plant death is not distributed equally across plants: changes in the real exchange rate have a stronger effect on the survival of the least efficient plants. This suggests a significant interaction effect between exchange-rate movements and the efficiency level of a plant.
1.2 Plant death and symmetric tariff reductions
The heterogeneous-firm-based models of international trade (Melitz and Ottaviano 2008; Bernard et al. 2003; Yeaple 2002; Melitz 2003; Baldwin and Gu 2009) all generate the equilibrium property that a symmetric reduction in bilateral tariff reductions forces the least efficient firms to exit. Exporters are less likely to fail than non-exporters, as a result of the higher efficiency of the former.
A number of papers have investigated the effects of declining tariffs on industry dynamics (Head and Ries 1999; Gu et al. 2003; Lileeva 2008). They find that a fall in Canadian tariffs increased exit rates of Canadian firms. Bernard, Jensen, and Schott (2003) further find evidence supporting the major hypotheses of the heterogeneous-firm models. They find that low-productivity non-exporters are more likely to die and that declines in trade costs increase the probability of death. Pérez et al. (2004) find that exporting firms enjoy better survival prospects.
- Hypothesis 2: Falling tariffs force the least efficient firms to exit. In other words, a fall in tariffs is expected to have a stronger effect on the death of a plant that is least efficient. This suggests a significant interaction effect between tariff cuts and the efficiency level of a plant.
- Hypothesis 3: Non-exporters, compared to exporters, are more likely to die as a result of the lower efficiency of the former.
1.3 Plant death and other risk factors
There has been a profusion of theoretical and empirical work in the industrial-organization literature on entry and exit of firms. One stylized fact (Dunne 1988; Baldwin 1995; Geroski 1995; Baldwin et al. 2000) is that size and age are positively related to a plant's probability of survival. Both the "liability of newness" effect (Stinchcombe 1965) and the selection models (Jovanovic, 1982; Pakes and Ericson 1998) suggest that new entrants and smaller plants are at a greater risk of failure compared with older and larger plants. New plants go through a process of learning after entry. This involves solving a range of problems, from acquiring suitable capital, to training a new workforce, establishing an appropriate organizational structure, and establishing upstream and downstream links with suppliers and customers (the "liability of newness" effect). New plants tend to be small relative to the minimum efficient scale; the likelihood of survival for small firms is lower because they are confronted by a scale cost disadvantage (the "selection" effect). Unlike large plants, small plants may not have ready access to capital and labour markets; 2 this in turn increases operating costs and their chances of exit.
- Hypothesis 4: Younger plants are more likely to die.
- Hypothesis 5: Smaller plants are more likely to die.
In addition to the effect of age and size on plant exit, selection models by Jovanovic (1982) and Ericson and Pakes (1995) also suggest that low-productivity plants have a higher probability of exit. Jovanovic's (1982) model is based on passive learning. Entering plants do not know their efficiency levels before entering the market. After entry, new plants learn about their relative efficiency through natural selection. The less efficient plants exit, while the most efficient ones survive and grow. In contrast, in the models of Ericson and Pakes (1995) and Pakes and Ericson (1998), each firm's performance and survival are driven by firm-specific active learning and investments in R&D and in innovation activities.
- Hypothesis 6: Less productive plants are more likely to die.
The relationship that should be expected between foreign ownership and plant exit is less clear. Various theoretical models have considered the role of foreign ownership with regard to the probability of plant exit. If foreign-owned subsidiaries have access to superior technologies, this would suggest that this group is more efficient and is less likely to exit. According to the resource-based view of firms (Wernerfelt 1984), the chances of survival depend to a large extent on a firm's ability to develop specific capabilities. On the one hand, multinationals are the type of firms that develop special-knowledge assets (Caves 2007) and have a greater propensity to be engaged in R&D, product innovation, and technological collaboration (Baldwin and Gu 2006); this may improve both their competitiveness and their chances of survival. On the other hand, in comparison with purely domestic plants, multinationals may have a higher elasticity of labour demand as a result of their enhanced ability to shift production across locations or outsource intermediate inputs from foreign plants (Riker and Brainard 1997; Brainard and Riker 1997). Since foreign multinational enterprises (MNEs) are less rooted in the local economy, they can shift their production to another country when the local economy deteriorates. The latter factors should increase the probability of shutdown, when faced with deteriorating domestic economic conditions.
The empirical evidence on foreign ownership and plant closure is mixed as well (Harris and Li 2007). For example, Bernard and Jensen (2002) find that plants owned by U.S. multinationals are more likely to close than similar plants of non-multinational firms. Görg and Strobl (2003) report a greater probability of exit for Irish plants that are foreign-owned. Li and Guisinger (1991) find that domestic entrants are more likely to exit than foreign ones.
- Hypothesis 7: Foreign-owned plants may be either more or less likely to die compared with domestic-owned plants.
2 Data source and summary statistics
2.1 Data on real exchange rates
To investigate the impact of exchange-rate movements on plant survival,
we use industry-specific real exchange rates between Canada and the United
States. The real exchange rate for industry i (Ei)
is constructed as the normal exchange rate (NER, expressed in terms
of U.S. dollars per Canadian dollar) deflated by U.S. (
) and Canadian industry (
) prices,
respectively. That is:
. The nominal exchange rate is taken from
Statistics Canada's CANSIM database. Canadian industry prices are from
a database maintained by the Economic Analysis Division of Statistics Canada.
They are gross output prices from the Input/Output system and cover 236 four-digit
Canadian manufacturing industries from 1973 to 1997. The U.S.
gross output prices are derived from the U.S. NBER-CES Manufacturing Industry
Database, a joint effort between the National Bureau of Economic Research
(NBER) and the U.S. Census Bureau's Center for Economic Studies (CES). The
NBER-CES Manufacturing Industry Database covers 459 U.S. manufacturing
industries from 1958 to 1996. They are matched and aggregated
to the 236 Canadian manufacturing industries.
An alternative to constructing industry-specific real exchange rates is
to calculate the exchange rate as a weighted average of exchange rates between
Canada and its trading partners, with weights being the countries' trade
shares for each industry (Baggs et al. 2009). There are two problems
with the use of this rate for studies of firm reaction to movements in exchange
rates. Firstly, the Canadian trade-weighted real exchange rates suffer from
the lack of variability across industries since the United States is our predominant
trading partner across manufacturing industries (this is indeed the case since,
when year dummies are included, Baggs et al. (2009) find that real
exchange rates tend to have an insignificant impact). Secondly, this rate
assumes same price adjustments to nominal exchange-rate movements across industries.
However, Baldwin and Yan (2007) find large heterogeneity in industries'
responses. The price-adjusted real exchange rate is a better indicator of
an industry's international competitiveness. It measures the price spread
between an industry's product price and the landed price charged by
industries in other countries. International competitiveness is affected not
only by the nominal exchange rate but also by domestic and foreign price movements.
For example, if the Canadian dollar appreciates against the U.S. dollar (an
increase in NER) but this is offset by movements in the relative inflation
rate of Canada (a decrease in
, there is no change in the competitive pressure
faced by Canadian firms as a result of the exchange-rate movement. What is
relevant to competitive pressures is the movement in relative domestic prices
in each country. Changes in the nominal exchange rate have a potential impact
only in respect of an industry's competitiveness. The actual shifts
in competitiveness depend on the ability and the speed with which the industry
adjusts its prices to changes in the nominal exchange rate. 3 When the real exchange rate increases,
Canadian manufacturers are placed under more pressure by U.S exporters as
they lose competitiveness. When the real exchange rate experiences a downward
trend, Canadian industries become more competitive relative to their foreign
counterparts.
The Canadian dollar has gone through several cycles of appreciation and depreciation relative to U.S. dollar. It first appreciated in the early 1970s after a period of a fixed exchange rate against the U.S. dollar. It depreciated between the mid-1970s and mid-1980s; this depreciation was followed by an appreciation in the late 1980s. The Canadian dollar then experienced a long period of depreciation over almost the entire decade of the 1990s; since 2002, the Canadian dollar has appreciated considerably, from US$0.64 in 2002 to US$0.93 in 2007. Chart 1 plots the nominal and real exchange rates for the manufacturing sector from 1960 to 2007, using Canadian and U.S. manufacturing GDP deflators for the real exchange rate. 4 Prices are all indexed to 1961. The real exchange rate for the manufacturing sector tracks the movement of the nominal exchange rate, indicating the stickiness of Canada/U.S. prices. Prices do not adjust to movements in the nominal exchange rate immediately.
We divide the entire period 1979-1996 into three sub-periods: 1979-1984; 1984-1990; and 1990-1996. They roughly correspond to the depreciation and appreciation cycles of the Canadian dollar. They also roughly correspond to the periods preceding and the periods following the Free Trade Agreement between Canada and the United States of America (FTA between Canada and the United States), which came into force in 1989, and the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), which came into force in 1994.
Summary statistics of exchange-rate changes over the three periods are provided in Table 1. The Canadian dollar depreciated at an average annual rate of 1.63 percentage points between 1979 and 1984, and at an average annual rate of 2.06 percentage points from 1990 to 1996, against the U.S. dollar. It appreciated at an annual average rate of 1.42 percentage points from 1984 to 1990. The average real exchange rate over 236 manufacturing industries experienced a pattern of movements similar to that for the nominal exchange rate. The standard deviations for the real exchange rate are large, indicating substantial variations across industries. In the next section, we investigate how plant survival differs systematically with changes in real exchange-rate movements across industries.
2.2 Data on tariff reductions
The Canadian manufacturing sector has also had to adapt to increasing trade liberalization. The Kennedy, Tokyo, and Uruguay rounds of international-trade liberalization led to falling tariffs in the 1960s, 1970s, and 1980s. The FTA and NAFTA followed up with even larger tariff reductions than had been experienced in previous decades.
To investigate the effect of tariff reductions on plant survival, we use bilateral tariffs between Canada and the United States as our measure of trade costs. More specifically, we use the average of Canadian tariff reductions against U.S. imports and U.S. tariff reductions against Canadian exports. 5 Data on Canadian tariffs against the U.S. and on U.S. tariffs against Canada are available from 1980 to 1996 for 236 four-digit manufacturing industries. 6 The data are constructed on the basis of import duties by commodity. Commodities are linked to their primary industries of production. Average industry tariffs are then calculated using import values as weights. 7
Table 1 shows that tariff reductions between Canada and the U.S. are large, at an annual average rate of 0.22 percentage points during 1979-1984, 0.33 percentage points during 1984-1990, and 0.62 percentage points during 1990-1996.
2.3 Data on plants
The plant-level data come from Statistic Canada's ASM database, a longitudinal database that tracks Canadian manufacturing plants over time. 8 It has information on shipments, value-added, employment, age of plants, nationality of ownership control, exports, and industry affiliation at the 1980 four-digit Canadian Standard Industrial Classification. Information on export status is available only for 1979, 1984, 1990, 1993, 1996, and 1997 for plants that filled out the long form. 9 Exits are defined for the purposes of this study as plants that completely cease to report any data. 10
Table 2 contains sample statistics for plant characteristics. The number of plants in manufacturing increased slightly over time, from 34,000 in 1979, to 38,000 in 1984, and to 42,000 in 1990. Distributions of plant characteristics are skewed. For example, the majority of plants have lower labour productivity than the mean. The same is true of plant size. Over the entire period, around 65% of plants had a value of labour productivity that was below the four-digit industry average, and around 74% of plants had a labour employment that was below the industry average. A small percentage of plants were exporters (16%). On average, foreign-controlled plants accounted for 14% of all plants. The number of foreign-controlled plants decreased steadily over time, from 16.2% in 1979, to 13.8% in 1984, and to 12.3% in 1990. At the same time, the number of exporters increased from 13.1% in 1984 to 21% in 1990; this increase coincided with the coming into force of the FTA between Canada and the United States, in 1989.
We also find that plant turnover increased. The incidence of plant exits increased from 31.2% in the 1979-to-1984 period to about 37% in the latter two periods. Most exiting plants were small; their output shares accounted for only about 11% over the three periods. There are major differences between the characteristics of exiting and those of continuing plants (Table 3). Over the three periods, exiting plants were less productive, smaller, younger, and more likely to be non-exporters and domestic-controlled plants than continuing plants.
There are also major differences in the characteristics of exporters and non-exporters, and between those of domestic- and foreign- controlled plants (Table 4). Exporters and foreign-controlled plants accounted for an average of 16% and 14% of all Canadian manufacturing plants, respectively. Exporters and foreign-controlled plants were more productive, larger, and older than non-exporters and domestic-controlled plants.
3 Empirical specification and results
Building on existing trade models involving heterogeneous firms (Melitz and Ottaviano 2008; Melitz 2003; Bernard et al. 2003; Baldwin and Gu 2009), we summarize a plant's decision to exit with:
where c* is the critical cost cut-off threshold, at which point a plant earns zero expected profit. A plant is hypothesized to exit if its cost cpt at period t is more than the threshold and thus the plant earns negative expected profit.
We further assume that the cost level of a plant depends on a combination of plant characteristics, industry shocks relating to tariff reductions, and the real exchange rate, as well as the interactions of these factors. That is:
where
is a vector of coefficients (
and x is a vector of independent variables
that include a vector of industry-wide changes in tariffs and real exchange
rates (
), and a vector of plant-level characteristics at the beginning
year of a period t0 (
). Plant-level characteristics include relative
labour productivity (relative to its four-digit industry average), relative
plant size measured in terms of employment (relative to its four-digit industry
average), and age. Note that changes in tariffs and real-exchange-rates are
at four-digit industry level. They are treated as exogenous, rather than endogenous,
or choice, factors, for each individual plant. While the real exchange rate
depends on industry pricing decisions of the largest firms in each industry
and might for some studies be considered endogenous, exit is primarily a phenomenon
of small plants that take the pricing decisions of the large firms as given.
Accordingly, equation (1) is rewritten as
where
is the standard normal cumulative distribution.
Two econometric issues need to be addressed before we present results. Firstly, equation (3) could be estimated by using a fixed-effects model, which typically includes a set of year and industry dummies, in order to control for unobserved heterogeneity across plants and over time. An alternative to this common practice is to demean all variables.
We experimented with these two approaches. They produce exactly the same
results when there are no interaction terms. With interactions, the two are
almost, but not quite, the same. This is because most statistical programs
such as STATA would not know, for example, that the independent variable
is
an interaction term between
and
. Including a set of period and industry dummies
in the case of equation (3) is equivalent to subtracting
the mean of (
) from the product of
and
(
). This is not the same as the product of
the demeaned
and
, as it should be.
Even though the two approaches are essentially equivalent, the latter allows
us to more easily interpret the marginal effects. We therefore adopt the demeaned
approach. We demean variables
and
before estimating equation (3). Period and two-digit industry specific averages are subtracted from
these variables. (To be consistent with fixed-effects model, variable Xit is demeaned as follows:
, where xit is the
demeaned Xit,
is the average for each two-digit industry i,
is the average for each time period t, and
is
the average of
over all two-digit industries or the average of
over
all time periods.) The interaction terms are the products of the demeaned
variables
and
.
Secondly, the inclusion of interaction terms makes the evaluation and interpretation of the results difficult and, in the past, has resulted in many incorrect estimates. Ai and Norton (2003) found that, among 72 articles published between 1980 and 1999 in 13 economics journals listed on JSTOR (a U.S.-based online system for archiving academic journals) that used interaction terms in nonlinear models, none of the studies interpreted the coefficient on the interaction term correctly. Since coefficients in probit models with interaction terms are hard to interpret (Ai and Norton 2003; Norton, Wang, and Ai 2004), we focus instead on the marginal effects when presenting results 11 . Marginal effects for interaction terms are calculated according to the following formulas:
The marginal effects of changes in tariffs and real exchange rates on plant exit are calculated as follows:
Similarly, the marginal effects of plant characteristics on exit are calculated as follows 12 :
3.1 Impact of tariff cuts on exit: all plants
We estimated equation (3) using a probit model. Marginal effects are reported in Table 6—and are based on the probit coefficient estimates reported in Table 5. Marginal effects are evaluated at industry mean values of all underlying variables. For all manufacturing plants, tariff cuts have a negative effect on exit that is statistically significant at the 1% level. A one-percentage-point reduction in tariffs increases the probability of exit by 4.7 percent. Further, the effect of tariff reductions on the probability of plant exit depends on the level of a plant's productivity: higher-productivity plants are less likely to die as a result of a given fall in tariffs since the marginal effect on the interaction term between tariff changes and productivity is positive and statistically significant at the 1% level. The interaction terms for the other variables are not statistically significant.
To demonstrate how marginal effects vary with plant characteristics, we
graph the marginal effects of tariff changes across the observed range of
relative productivity, relative employment, and age, respectively (Charts 2, 3 and 4). 13 The solid sloping line in Chart 2, for example, indicates how the marginal effects of
tariff changes vary with relative productivity. Any particular point on this
line is
, where all xs—except relative productivity,
which is allowed to vary—are evaluated at industry mean values. Ninety-five-percent
confidence intervals around the line allow us to determine the points at which
tariff reductions have a statistically significant effect on exit. The effect
is significant whenever the upper and lower bounds of the confidence interval
are either above or below the zero line.
These confidence intervals indicate that changes in tariffs have strong negative effects on the probability of exit when productivity is low. This negative effect declines as productivity increases. Once a plant's productivity is 1.6 times more than its industry average (or a plant's relative productivity deviates from the industry mean of one by 0.6 units as shown on the graph), 14 a change in tariffs no longer has a significant negative impact on plant death. This result is significant, since the productivity of roughly 88% of plants is less than 1.6 times the industry average. In other words, a fall in tariffs has a significant effect on the survival of 88% of manufacturing plants, whose productivity is less than 1.60 times the industry average. Within this group of plants, the negative effect of tariffs on death declines as productivity increases.
The marginal effects of tariff cuts are plotted against relative employment and age in Charts 3 and 4. A decline in tariffs has a significant impact on the survival of 84 percent of manufacturing plants—those whose employment is less than 1.60 times industry average employment, and on the survival of 82 percent of manufacturing plants, those that are either older than the average industry plant age or younger by not more than five years. Within these two groups of plants, the negative effect declines with employment size, but increases with age. However, as we will demonstrate in Table 7, this change in the negative effect of employment size and age is not statistically significant.
The marginal effects are calculated in Table 6 by relative labour productivity, relative employment, and age quartiles. The marginal impacts in these quartile groups are evaluated at the mean of all variables—except the variable used to classify quartiles, which is evaluated at quartile mean values. As was found in Charts 2, 3 and 4, a reduction in tariffs significantly increases the exit rate for plants in the lowest three quartiles, defined in terms of productivity and employment, but has no significant impact for plants in the highest quartiles. In addition, the marginal effect drops as productivity or employment moves from the lowest quartile to the highest quartile. In particular, the differences among the four quartile groups in terms of productivity are significant at the 5% level, but insignificant among the four quartile groups in terms of employment. Tariff reductions impact on plant survival for all age groups, but are marginally significant only for the youngest group, and the differences among the four groups are not statistically significant.
In sum, we find tariff reductions have strong negative effects on the probability of plant exit. A fall in tariffs increases the likelihood of exit for around 80 percent of manufacturing plants with relatively low productivity. Within this group of plants, the negative effect declines as productivity increases. This supports hypothesis 2.
3.2 Impact of real exchange-rate changes on exit: all plants
Changes in the value of the Canadian dollar have a significant positive impact on plant exit. A one-percentage-point appreciation in the Canadian dollar raises the probability of exit by 0.3 percent, statistically significant at the 5% level. Furthermore, the effect of real-exchange-rate changes on plant exit depends on the level of productivity: higher-productivity plants are less likely to die as a result of a given appreciation of the Canadian dollar since there is a negative marginal effect associated with the interaction term between real-exchange-rate changes and productivity that is statistically significant at the 1% level. The interaction terms for the other variables are not statistically significant (Table 7).
Marginal effects of changes in the real exchange rate are plotted against relative productivity, relative employment, and age, respectively in Charts 5, 6 and 7). Changes in the real exchange rate have strong positive effects on plant exit when productivity is low (Chart 5). This positive effect declines as productivity increases. Once a plant's productivity is 1.1 times more than its industry average (or a plant's relative productivity deviates from the industry mean of one by 0.1 units as shown on the graph), changes in the real exchange rate no longer have a significant positive impact on plant death. The result is substantive, since roughly 71% of plants have productivity that is less than 1.1 times the industry average. In other words, an appreciation of the Canadian dollar has a significant impact on the survival of 71% of manufacturing plants whose productivity lies below 1.1 times the industry average; furthermore, within this group of plants, the impact declines as productivity increases.
Marginal effects by the four quartiles in terms of productivity (Table 7) further confirm the results from Chart 5: an appreciation in the Canadian dollar significantly increases the exit rate for plants in the lowest three quartiles, but has no significant impact for plants in the highest quartile. The marginal effect drops as productivity moves from the lowest to the highest quartile; the differences among the four quartiles are statistically significant at the 5% level.
Not all characteristics are related to the impact of exchange-rate fluctuations. The marginal impact of fluctuations in the Canadian dollar on plant closure does not vary significantly across plants that differ in terms of employment size or age (Charts 6, 7 and Table 7).
In sum, we find that the value of the Canadian dollar has a strong positive effect on the probability of plant exit. An appreciation of the Canadian dollar increases the likelihood of plant failure for around 70 percent of manufacturing plants with relatively low productivity. Within this group of plants, the positive effect declines as productivity increases. This supports hypothesis 1.
3.3 Impact of industry characteristics on exit: all plants
We confirm previous research findings that plant size, age, and productivity are important determinants of plant survival. Younger, smaller, and less productive plants are more likely to die since there are statistically significant marginal effects on the relative productivity, relative employment, and age variables (Table 8); 15 negative slopes are associated with these variables in Charts 8, 9 and 10. The results are consistent with predictions arising from hypotheses 4, 5, and 6.
3.4 Non-exporter vs. exporters
To examine how changes in tariffs and real exchanges rates differentially affect the survival of exporters and non-exporters, we estimate equation (3) separately for exporters and non-exporters. A plant is defined as an exporter if it exports at the beginning of a period. All variables are demeaned as was done previously. Probit coefficient estimates for both exporters and non-exporters are reported in Table 5.
The predicted exit rate for the two groups over the entire range of actual changes in tariffs and real exchange rates is plotted in Charts 11 and 12. Three conclusions can be drawn. First, tariff reductions are negatively associated with the predicted probability of exit for both exporters and non-exporters, while increases in the real value of the Canadian dollar are positively associated with the predicted probability of exit. This confirms our findings, reported in sections 2.1 and 2.2, that a fall in tariffs or a real appreciation in the Canadian dollar increases the probability of exit.
Second, the predicted exit rate for non-exporters is higher than the predicted exit rate for exporters 16 : 37.2 percent for non-exporters and 21.0 percent for exporters (Table 9). The marginal effect of being an exporter (the difference) is statistically significant at the 5% level. This supports hypothesis 3. Non-exporters are less efficient—less productive, smaller, and younger (Table 5). Their cost disadvantage leads to a higher probability of exit.
Third, the marginal effects of changes in tariffs and in real exchange rates on exit are significantly greater for exporters than for non-exporters—as is evidenced by the steeper slopes for exporters in Charts 11 and 12, and by the higher marginal effects calculated in Tables 6 and 7. 17
When an exporter and a non-exporter have similar efficiency levels in terms of productivity, size, and age (i.e., controlling for plant characteristics by evaluating marginal impacts at the common industry mean values of relative productivity, relative employment, and age), changes in tariffs and real exchange rates have a greater impact on the exit probability of the exporter: the marginal effects are -10.0 percent and 1.1 percent respectively for exporters, compared with -3.7 percent and 0.1 percent for non-exporters. The difference between them is statistically significant (Tables 6 and 7).
Since exporters are more efficient than non-exporters, we expect that, after allowing for varying group characteristics by evaluating marginal impacts at the group-specific industry mean values of relative productivity, relative employment, and age in order to take into account efficiency levels, the effect on the exit of exporters will be reduced and the effect on the exit of non-exporters will be increased. As expected, we find that the marginal impacts are reduced to -7.0 percent and 0.8 percent, respectively, for exporters, but increased to -3.9 percent and 0.2 percent, respectively, for non-exporters. The effect on exporters, however, remains significantly greater than the effect on non-exporters (Tables 6 and 7). This suggests that, besides the differences in efficiency levels as measured by the variables included here, exporters and non-exporters differ in other important ways that make the survival of exporters more sensitive to changes in tariffs and real exchange rates than the survival of non-exporters. It follows that one should not infer from the heterogeneous firms' models that a fall in trade costs increases the likelihood of plant exit for non-exporters more than for exporters simply because non-exporters are at the lower end of productivity distribution. The productivity or efficiency level of a plant as measured by productivity is not the only factor determining the survival of plants. There are other important differences between exporters and non-exporters that are not captured by the efficiency characteristics used in the analysis. One possible explanation is that international-oriented plants such as exporters face more intense competition than do domestic-oriented plants such as non-exporters. Exporters, by their very nature, are in a world where changes in tariffs and the exchange rate immediately affect their profit margin and therefore the likelihood of their survival. They may also have different cut-offs that lead to more rapid adjustment.
Other evidence suggests that exporters and non-exporters respond differently to changes in trade costs. Baldwin and Gu (2009) examined the impact of tariff reductions on the length of production runs and found that exporters were more likely to increase their production runs and exploit scope economies than were non-exporters over the 1990s. These two results suggest that changes in tariffs and in real exchange rates generate more turnover and adjustment among exporters than among non-exporters, and it is possible that these factors have a greater effect on both the death rate and the birth rate—but additional research is required here.
The above results indicate that exporters are more sensitive than non-exporters to changes in tariffs and real exchange rates. We further show that the higher-productivity plants of exporters are less likely to die, as evidenced by the positive and significant marginal effect on the interaction term between tariff changes and productivity (Table 6), and by the negative and significant marginal effect on the interaction term between real-exchange-rate changes and productivity (Table 7). The marginal effects by quartile set out in Tables 6 and 7, which show that differences in the marginal effects are significant across the four quartiles ranked in terms of productivity among exporters, further confirm this. We do not find a significant interaction effect for non-exporters.
In sum, we find that the predicted exit rate for non-exporters is much higher than the predicted exit rate for exporters, and that a fall in tariffs or an appreciation of the Canadian dollar increases the probability of plant failure for both exporters and non-exporters (but does so significantly more for exporters). Among exporters, plants with low productivity are more likely to be affected. Our results suggest that exporters' deaths, in particular those of exporters with lower productivity, are driven largely by external changes in tariffs and in the real exchange rate, while the death of non-exporters is driven largely by their internal characteristics relating to their lower efficiency, which stems from their lower productivity, smaller size, or younger age.
3.5 Domestic-controlled vs. foreign-controlled plants
To examine how changes in tariff rates and in real exchange rates differentially affect the survival of domestic- and foreign-controlled plants, we estimate equation (3) separately for the two groups. A plant is defined as domestic- or foreign-controlled by its status at the beginning of a period. Probit coefficient estimates for both domestic- and foreign-controlled plants are reported in Table 5.
The predicted exit rate based on the estimated probit coefficients is plotted in Charts 13 and 14 for the two groups over the entire range of actual changes in tariff reductions and in the real exchange rate. Two conclusions emerge.
First, domestic-controlled plants have a higher probability of exit than foreign-controlled plants (Charts 13 and 14). The predicted exit rate is 35.7 percent for domestic-controlled plants, and 26.4 percent for foreign-controlled plants. The marginal effect of being a foreign-controlled plant (i.e., the difference) is statistically significant (Table 9). Foreign-controlled plants are more efficient, whether they derive their cost advantage from being more productive or larger, thus achieving economies of scale, or from being older, thus having absorbed expertise through more learning-by-doing (Table 4). That foreign-controlled plants are more likely to survive suggests that these plants are better endowed with specific superior capabilities that improve plants' competitiveness and survival.
Second, the marginal effects of changes in tariff rates and in real exchange rates on changes in the probability of exit are larger for foreign- than for domestic- controlled plants, as is evidenced by the steeper slopes for foreign-controlled plants in Charts 13 and 14, and by the marginal effects calculated in Tables 6 and 7.
When a domestic-controlled plant and a foreign-controlled plant have similar efficiency levels in terms of productivity, employment, and age, changes in tariffs and real exchange rates have a greater impact on the exit probability of the foreign-controlled plant: the marginal effects of tariffs and real exchanges rates are -10.0 percent and 0.7 percent, respectively, for foreign-controlled plants, compared with -4.6 percent and 0.2 percent, respectively, for domestic-controlled plants. The difference between them is statistically significant (Tables 6 and 7). One possible explanation is that a multinational has a greater capability, and thus a higher likelihood, to shift its production to another country whenever the domestic Canadian environment changes to its disadvantage. Another possible explanation is that multinationals are more sensitive to changes in profitability.
Since foreign-controlled plants are more efficient than domestic-controlled plants, we expect that, after their efficiency levels are taken into account, the effect on the exit of foreign-controlled plants will be reduced and the effect on domestic-controlled plants will be increased. As expected, we find that the marginal impacts are reduced to -5.8 percent and 0.5 percent, respectively, for foreign-controlled plants, but remain virtually unchanged for domestic-controlled plants. As a result, the differences in the marginal effects between domestic-and foreign- controlled plants become insignificant (Tables 6 and 7). This suggests that the survival prospects of foreign-controlled plants are more sensitive to changes in tariffs and real exchange rates. The differential impact, however, becomes insignificant once we take into account differences in the efficiency levels, as measured here.
3.6 A counterfactual experiment
These results indicate that the impact of tariff reductions and real-exchange-rate changes on the likelihood of plant survival is statistically significant. To evaluate whether these impacts have economic significance, we conduct a counterfactual experiment. The counterfactual experiment proceeds as follows. First, we assume there were no changes in tariffs and real-exchange-rates, and calculate the corresponding predicted exit rate. The predicted exit rates under this case are caused by factors other than changes in tariffs and real exchange rates. Second, we calculate predicted exit rates by allowing actual changes in tariffs but holding changes in real exchange rates at zero. The difference in the predicted exit rates between case two and case one is the amount of failure induced by tariff changes. Third, we calculate predicted exit rates by setting changes in tariffs at zero but allowing actual changes in real exchange rates. The difference in the predicted exit rates between case three and case one is the failure resulting from changes in real exchange rates. Lastly, we allow actual changes in both tariffs and real exchange rates. The difference in predicted exit rates between case four and case one is the failure rates brought about by simultaneous changes in both tariffs and real exchange rates. In all cases, predicted exit rates are calculated using estimated coefficients in Table 5 and evaluated at the mean values of independent variables. 18
3.6.1 All plants
The contribution of tariff cuts and real-exchange-rate changes to plant death are substantial. Results of the counterfactual experiment for all manufacturing plants are reported in Table 10. When there were no changes in tariffs and real exchange rates, the average predicted failure rate is around 25.3 percent over the three periods. The rate increased to an average of 34.3 percent when we allow actual changes in both tariffs and real exchange rates. Between 1984 and 1990, when the Canadian dollar appreciated against the U.S dollar, tariff cuts explain approximately 70 percent of the increase, while appreciation explains approximately 30 percent of the increase. During periods when the Canadian dollar depreciated (1979-1984 and 1990-1996), the increase in the predicted exit rate is attributable mostly to tariff reductions, but is partially offset by the depreciation of the Canadian dollar. During the implementation of NAFTA, in the 1990s, Canada experienced a substantial depreciation in its currency, which offset about 17% of the impact of falling tariffs during this period.
3.6.2 Exporters vs. non-exporters
We repeat the experiment for exporters and non-exporters. We confirm our previous findings that changes in tariffs and real exchange rates have a much greater incidence on the survival of exporters than on that of non-exporters.
Tariff cuts increase failure rates for both exporters and non-exporters, but more so for exporters. The difference is more prominent between 1990 and 1996, when there were deep tariff cuts under the FTA and NAFTA. During this period, tariff cuts induced an estimated failure rate of 21.2 percent for exporters, compared with 13.2 percent for non-exporters (Table 11).
The survival of exporters is at least twice as sensitive as that of non-exporters to fluctuations in real exchange rates. Between 1984 and 1990, when the Canadian dollar appreciated, plant exit induced by the appreciation is 4.6 percent for exporters, compared with only 1.6 percent for non-exporters. During periods when the Canadian dollar depreciated against the U.S dollar (1979-1984 and 1990-1996), the depreciation increases the likelihood of plant survival by 1.6 percent and 3.5 percent for exporters for the two periods, respectively, compared with 0.04 percent and 1.7 percent for non-exporters (Table 11).
3.6.3 Domestic- vs. foreign- controlled plants
Finally, we repeat the experiment for domestic- and foreign- controlled plants. We confirm our previous findings that changes in tariffs and real exchange rates have a much greater incidence on the survival of foreign-controlled plants than on the survival of domestic-controlled plants.
Tariff cuts induced higher failure rates for foreign-controlled plants than for domestic-controlled plants. The exception is the last period (1990-1996), when domestic-controlled plants underwent higher tariff cuts (3.5 percent) than did foreign-controlled plants (2.9 percent) during the period (Table 12).
The survival of foreign-controlled plants is about 2.3 times more sensitive than that of domestic-controlled plants to fluctuations in real exchange rates. Between 1984 and 1990, when the Canadian dollar appreciated, plant exit induced by the appreciation is 4.0 percent for foreign-controlled plants, compared with 1.7 percent for domestic-controlled plants. During periods when the Canadian dollar depreciated against the U.S dollar (1979-1984 and 1990-1996), the depreciation increased the likelihood of plant survival by 0.2 percent and 3.8 percent for foreign-controlled plants for the two periods, respectively, compared with 0.1 percent and 1.6 percent for domestic-controlled plants (Table 12) .
4 Conclusion
This paper examines the effect of tariff reductions and real-exchange-rate changes on plant death over a long period of tariff cuts and exchange-rate cycles. Included in the analysis is a set of factors that are hypothesized to affect plant closure: productivity; size; age; export and foreign-control status of plants; and changes in tariffs and real exchange rates. A probit model and a panel of Canadian manufacturing plants over the period of 1979-1996 are used to adduce empirical evidence on the simultaneous effect of tariff reductions and real-exchange-rate fluctuations on plant survival. Differences between exporters and non-exporters, and between domestic- and foreign- controlled plants, are also investigated.
Real-exchange-rate fluctuations are found to be strongly associated with plant shutdown, and the effect is significant both statistically and in terms of its impact on the economy. A real appreciation of the Canadian dollar relative to the U.S. dollar significantly increases the probability of plant death; a real appreciation of one percentage point in the currency value increases the likelihood of plant exit by 0.3 percent. Our counterfactual experiment indicates that this translates into a failure rate of 2.8 percent between 1984 and 1990, when the Canadian dollar appreciated by 9.4 percentage points; this represents an 11.6-percent increase from the 24.0-percent failure rate that we estimate for a situation where there are no changes in tariffs and real exchange rates. In contrast, the real depreciation of the Canadian dollar from 1979 to 1984 and from 1990 to 1996 significantly increases the probability of plant survival. During the implementation of NAFTA, in the 1990s, the Canadian economy experienced a substantial depreciation in its currency that offset about 17% of the impact of falling tariffs during this period.
The effect of exchange-rate movements on plant exit is not uniform across plants. When the real value of a currency appreciates, less efficient plants experience a greater probability of exiting. Similarly, when the real value of a currency depreciates, plants that are less efficient are more likely to survive.
Changes in tariffs are shown to be strongly associated with the likelihood of exit; the impact is statistically significant and substantial. The counterfactual experiment shows that, between 1990 and 1996, when extensive tariff cuts were effected under the FTA and NAFTA, tariff reductions induced a 15-percent failure rate, a 67.5-percent increase in the failure rates compared with the case when there were no tariff cuts. The impact is not felt equally across plants. Falling tariffs increase the likelihood of plant death, in particular, for plants that are less efficient.
Overall, for the periods examined, tariff reductions play a more important role in plant exits than do exchange-rate fluctuations. For the period 1984 to 1990, the magnitude of plant failure resulting from tariff reduction is around 2.6 times that of plant failure resulting from exchange-rate appreciation. The depreciation of the Canadian dollar over the period 1990-1996 led to a decrease in the exit rate, but this decline only partially offset the increased exit probability resulting from tariff cuts that occurred at the same time.
We find significant differences between exporters and non-exporters: the probability of exit is different; and they respond differently to changes in tariffs and real exchange rates. On the one hand, failure rates are much higher for non-exporters. They are less efficient, as a result of their being less productive, smaller, or younger. On the other hand, the survival probability of exporters is strongly affected by changes in tariffs and real exchange rates, much more so than that of non-exporters. The difference is statistically significant and substantial, whether or not we control for efficiency differences between exporters and non-exporters. The results indicate that the death of exporters, in particular exporters with lower productivity, is driven largely by changes in tariffs and exchange rates, while the death of non-exporters is driven mainly by the inherent characteristics that make them less efficient.
We also find significant differences between domestic- and foreign-controlled plants. On the one hand, failure rates are much higher for domestic-controlled plants. Domestic-controlled plants are typically less efficient; this is the result of their being less productive, smaller, or younger. On the other hand, the survival probability of foreign-controlled plants is affected to a greater extent by changes in tariffs and real exchange rates. However, once we take into account their efficiency differences, this differential impact becomes insignificant.
Our finding on the higher survival sensitivity of exporters and foreign-controlled plants to changes in tariffs and real exchange rates suggests that, besides the differences in efficiency levels, there are other important differences between exporters and non-exporters, and between domestic- and foreign- controlled plants, that are not captured by the efficiency characteristics used in the analysis.
- Date modified: